[Background Material and Data on Programs within the Jurisdiction of the Committee on Ways and Means (Green Book)]
[Program Descriptions]
[Section 1. Social Security: The Old Age, Survivors, and Disability Insurance (OASDI) Programs]
[From the U.S. Government Printing Office, www.gpo.gov]





 
SECTION 1 - SOCIAL SECURITY: THE OLD-AGE, SURVIVORS, AND 
DISABILITY INSURANCE (OASDI) PROGRAMS

CONTENTS

General
   Brief History of Social Security Programs
   Who is Covered by Social Security?
Social Security's Financing and the Social Security Trust Funds
   Current Law
   Where Do Social Security Taxes Go and How Are They Used?
   How the Solvency of the Trust Funds is Measured
   Findings in Latest Trustees Report
   Historical Status of the Trust Funds
Trends Affecting the Financial Status of the Social Security Trust Funds
Social Security Benefits and Eligibility
   Benefit Eligibility
   Benefits for the Worker's Family
   Benefit Computation
   Taxation of Benefits
   Disability Determination and the Claims Process
Social Security's Treatment in the Federal Budget
   Social Security's Off-Budget Status
   Budgetary Treatment of Administrative Expenses
   House and Senate Budget Procedures to Protect Social Security 
     Balances
Legislative History
   104th Congress
   105th Congress
   106th Congress
   107th Congress
Statistical Tables
   Tax Rates and Covered Earnings
   Covered Workers
   Benefit and Recipient Data
   Benefit Adjustments
   Effect of Current Earnings and Taxation of Benefits
   Trust Fund and Related Data
   Disability Program Data
Appendix: Relationship of Taxes to Benefits for Social Security 
   Retirees.--How Long It Takes To Recover the Value of Taxes Paid 
         Plus Interest
References




OVERVIEW

BRIEF HISTORY OF SOCIAL SECURITY PROGRAMS

Prior to the 20th century, the majority of people in the United States lived 
and worked on farms, and economic security was provided by the extended family. 
However, this arrangement changed as America underwent the Industrial 
Revolution. The extended family and the family farm as sources of economic 
security became less common. Then, the Great Depression triggered a crisis in 
the Nation's economic life. It was against this backdrop that the Social 
Security 
programs emerged. 
	Beginning in 1932, the Federal Government first made loans, then grants, 
to States to pay for direct relief and work relief. After that, special Federal 
emergency relief and public works programs were started. In 1935, President 
Franklin D. Roosevelt proposed to Congress economic security legislation 
embodying the recommendations of a specially created Committee on Economic 
Security. Then followed the passage of the Social Security Act (the Act), 
signed into law August 14, 1935.
	This law established two social insurance programs on a national scale 
to help meet the risks of old age and unemployment: a Federal system of old-age 
benefits for retired workers who had been employed in industry and commerce, 
and a Federal-State system of unemployment insurance. The choice of old age and 
unemployment as the risks to be covered by social insurance was a natural 
development, since the Depression had wiped out much of the lifetime savings of 
the aged and reduced opportunities for gainful employment. The Act also provided 
Federal grants-in-aid to the States for the means-tested programs of Old-Age 
Assistance and Aid to the Blind, which were replaced by the Supplemental 
Security Income program that was enacted in 1972. These programs supplemented 
the incomes of persons who were either ineligible for Social Security (Old-Age 
and Survivors Insurance (OASI)) or whose benefits could not provide a basic 
living. The intent of Federal participation was to encourage States to adopt 
such programs. The law established other Federal grants to enable States to 
extend and strengthen maternal and child health and welfare services. These 
latter grants became the Aid to Families with Dependent Children program, 
which was replaced in 1996 with a new block grant program, Temporary Assistance 
for Needy Families. The Act also provided Federal grants to States for public 
health and vocational rehabilitation services. Provisions for these grants were 
later removed from the Social Security Act and incorporated into other 
legislation.
	The Old-Age Insurance Program was not yet in full operation when 
significant changes were adopted. In 1939, Congress made the old-age insurance 
system a family program when it added benefits for dependents of retired workers 
and surviving dependents of deceased workers. Benefits also first became payable 
in 1940, instead of 1942 as originally planned. No major changes were made again 
in the program until the 1950s, when it was broadened to cover many jobs that 
previously had been excluded--in some cases because experience was needed to 
work out procedures for reporting the earnings and collecting the taxes of 
persons in certain occupational groups. The scope of the basic national social 
insurance system was significantly broadened in 1956 through the addition of 
disability insurance (DI). Benefits were provided for severely disabled workers 
aged 50 or older and for adult disabled children of deceased or retired workers. 
In 1958, the Social Security Act was further amended to provide benefits for 
dependents of disabled workers similar to those already provided for dependents 
of retired workers. In 1960, the age 50 requirement for disabled worker benefits 
was removed. The 1967 amendments provided disability benefits for widows and 
widowers aged 50 or older.
The 1972 amendments provided for automatic cost-of-living increases in 
benefits tied to increases in the Consumer Price Index (CPI) and created the 
delayed retirement credit, which increased benefits for workers who retire after 
the full retirement age (FRA) (then age 65).
The 1977 amendments changed the method of benefit computation to ensure 
stable earnings replacement rates over time. Earnings included in the computation 
were to be indexed to account for changes in the economy from the time they were 
earned.
The 1983 amendments made coverage compulsory for newly hired Federal 
civilian employees and for employees of nonprofit organizations. State and local 
governments were prohibited from opting out of the system once they had joined. 
The amendments also provided for gradual increases in the age of eligibility for 
full retirement benefits from 65 to 67, beginning with persons born in 1938.  For 
certain higher income beneficiaries, benefits became subject to income tax.  
Amendments in 1993 increased the amount of benefits subject to taxation.
    	The 1996 amendments relaxed earnings limits for seniors who have reached 
the FRA (age 65-67, depending on year of birth).
    	The 1999 amendments reformed certain provisions under the DI Program, 
specifically to create stronger incentives and better supports for individuals 
to work. 
    	An amendment passed in April 2000 (Public Law 106-182) eliminated the 
earnings limit for seniors who have reached the FRA, effective for the year 2000.

Concept of social insurance
	When the OASDI Programs were created, "insurance" was included in their 
titles to show that their purpose is to replace income lost to a family through 
the retirement, death, or disability of a worker who earned protection against 
these risks. This protection is earned by working in jobs that are covered under 
Social Security and therefore subject to payroll taxes that finance Social 
Security benefits. Once individuals work long enough in covered jobs to be 
insured, they and their families become eligible for their benefits as a matter 
of earned right. The level of benefits is based on the amount the worker earned 
in covered jobs, and is paid without a test of economic need. However, the 
social ends the programs serve diverge somewhat from the insurance analogy. The 
programs are national, and coverage is generally compulsory and nearly universal. 
They are designed to address social purposes such as alleviating poverty, 
providing added protection for families versus single workers, and providing a 
larger degree of earnings replacement for low-paid versus high-paid workers. 
The OASDI Programs were therefore described as "social" insurance.

WHO IS COVERED BY SOCIAL SECURITY?

    	In 1937, approximately 33 million persons worked in employment covered 
by the Social Security system. Over the years, major categories of workers were 
brought under the system, such as self-employed individuals, State and local 
government employees (on a voluntary basis at the option of the State), regularly 
employed farm and domestic workers, members of the armed services, and 
members of the clergy and religious orders (on a voluntary basis). In 2002, of a 
total work force of approximately 159.3 million workers, about 152.8 million 
workers and an estimated 96 percent of all jobs in the United States were covered 
under Social Security (Table 1-6). In 2002, an estimated 85 percent of all earnings 
from jobs covered by Social Security were taxable (Table 1-3).
    	While coverage is compulsory for most types of employment, approximately 
6.5 million workers did not have coverage under Social Security in 2002. The 
majority of these non-covered workers are in State and local governments or the 
Federal government (Tables 1-6 and 1-8). Beginning January 1, 1983, Federal 
employees were covered under the Medicare (HI) portion of the Social Security tax, 
and all Federal employees hired after 1983 are covered under the OASDI portion as 
well. In 2001, 72 percent of State and local government workers (16.9 million out 
of 23.6 million) were covered by Social Security. Beginning January 1, 1984, all 
employees of nonprofit organizations became covered, and as of April 1983, 
termination of Social Security coverage by State government entities was no longer 
allowed. State and local employees hired after March 31, 1986 are mandatorily 
covered under the Medicare program and must pay Hospital Insurance (HI) payroll 
taxes. Beginning July 1, 1991, State and local employees who were not members of 
a public retirement system were mandatorily covered under Social Security. This 
requirement was contained in the 1990 Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act 
(OBRA 1990, Public Law 101-508).

SOCIAL SECURITY'S FINANCING AND THE SOCIAL SECURITY 
TRUST FUNDS

CURRENT LAW

	The OASDI program and the Medicare HI program are primarily financed 
through the collection of payroll taxes under the Federal Insurance Contributions 
Act (FICA) and the Self-Employment Contributions Act (SECA). These taxes are 
levied on the wages and net self-employment income of workers covered by Social 
Security and Medicare.


The FICA tax is levied at a rate of 15.3 percent. The tax is shared by 
employees and their employers, with each paying half of the total amount.  
Employers may deduct their share of the FICA tax for income tax purposes, but the 
employee's share is not tax deductible. Of the total 15.3 percent FICA tax, 12.4 
percent is used to finance the OASDI Program, and 2.9 percent is used to finance 
the Medicare HI Program. The OASDI portion of the tax is levied on earnings up to 
$87,900 in 2004. This "taxable wage base" increases annually with average wage 
growth in the economy. The HI portion of the tax is levied on all earnings. When 
the FICA tax was first levied in 1937, the tax rate was 2 percent on earnings up 
to $3,000.
The SECA tax also is levied at a rate of 15.3 percent, with the same 12.4 
percent and 2.9 percent split between OASDI and HI as the FICA tax. Prior to 
1984, the SECA tax rate paid by self-employed workers was lower than the total 
FICA tax rate paid by employees and employers. Effective for 1984 through 1989, 
self-employed workers paid the same total tax as employees and employers, but 
received a partial credit against that tax liability. Effective in 1990 and 
thereafter, the credit was replaced with a system designed to achieve parity 
between employees and the self-employed. Under this system:  
	The base of the SECA tax is adjusted downward to reflect the fact that 
employees do not pay FICA taxes on the employer's portion of the FICA 
tax. The adjusted base is equivalent to net earnings from self-employment 
(up to the taxable wage base) less 7.65 percent.
	In addition, self-employed workers are allowed to deduct half of their 
SECA tax liability for income tax purposes to reflect the fact that 
employees do not pay income tax on the employer's portion of the FICA 
tax.
    	Tables 1-1 and 1-2 show FICA and SECA tax rates and maximum taxable 
earnings, both past and future.
    	The following workers are exempt from FICA and SECA taxes:
1.	State and local government workers participating in alternative 
retirement systems (HI tax is mandatory for State and local government 
workers hired since April 1,1986);
2.	Election workers earning $1,200 or less a year;
3.	Ministers who choose not to be covered, and certain religious sects;
4.	Federal workers hired before 1984 (the HI portion is mandatory for all 
Federal workers ;
5.	College students working at their academic institutions;
6.	Household workers earning less than $1,400 in 2004, or those under 
age 18 for whom household work is not their principal occupation; and
7.	Self-employed workers with annual net earnings below $400.

In addition to payroll taxes, the Social Security system is credited with 
income from the taxation of Social Security benefits and interest on trust 
fund balances.  In combination, these sources of income are used to pay Social 
Security benefits and administrative expenses. Administrative expenses are 
subject to an annual limitation set by appropriations acts.

WHERE DO SOCIAL SECURITY TAXES GO AND HOW ARE THEY USED?

    	The costs of the Social Security program, both its benefits and 
administrative expenses, are financed primarily by the FICA and SECA taxes. 
These taxes flow each day into thousands of depository accounts maintained by 
the government with financial institutions across the country. Along with many 
other forms of revenues, these Social Security taxes become part of the 
government's operating cash pool, or what is more commonly referred to as the 
U.S. Treasury. In effect, once these taxes are received, they become 
indistinguishable from other moneys the government takes in. They are accounted 
for separately through the issuance of Federal securities to the Social Security 
Trust Funds--which basically involves a series of bookkeeping entries by the 
Treasury Department--but the trust funds themselves do not hold money. They are 
simply accounts. Similarly, Social Security checks are paid from the Treasury, 
not the trust funds. As the checks are paid, securities of an equivalent value 
are removed from the trust funds.
  	In a sense, the mechanics of a Federal trust fund are similar to those 
of a bank account. The bank takes in a depositor's money, credits the amount 
to the depositor's account, and then loans it out. As long as the account 
shows a balance, the depositor can write checks that the bank must honor. 
When more Social Security taxes are received than spent, the balance of 
securities posted to the Social Security Trust Funds rises. The surplus taxes 
themselves are then used for any of the many functions of government. The trust
funds' Federal securities, like those sold to the public, are legal obligations 
of the government. The Social Security Trustees projected in March 2003 that the 
balances of the trust funds would reach $1.5 trillion by the end of calendar year
2003 (Table 1-29).
    	While generally the securities issued to the trust funds are not 
marketable, they do earn interest at market rates, have specific maturity dates, 
and represent legal obligations of the U.S. Government. What often confuses 
people is that they see these securities as assets for the government. When an 
individual buys a government bond, she has established a financial claim against 
the government. When the government issues a security to one of its own accounts, 
it hasn't purchased anything or established a claim against some other person or 
entity. It is simply creating an IOU from one of its accounts to another. Hence, 
building up Federal securities in Federal trust funds--like those of Social 
Security--is not a means in and of itself for the government to accumulate assets. 
It certainly establishes claims against the government for the Social Security 
program, but the program is part of the government. Those claims are not resources 
the government may use to pay future Social Security benefits. The key point is 
that the trust funds themselves do not hold resources to pay benefits. Rather, 
they provide authority for the Treasury Department to use whatever money it has 
on hand to pay them.
    	The significance of having trust funds for Social Security is that they 
represent a long-term commitment of the government to the program. While the 
funds do not hold "resources" that the government can call on to pay Social 
Security benefits, the balances of Federal securities posted to them represent 
and have served as financial claims against the government--claims on which the 
Treasury has never defaulted, nor used directly as a basis to finance anything 
but Social Security expenditures.
    	The trust fund arrangement is different from that used by other 
programs in government in that many other programs, particularly those not 
accounted for through trust funds, get their operating balances--i.e., their 
permission to spend--through the annual appropriations process. Congress must 
pass an appropriations act each year giving the Treasury Department permission 
to expend funds for them. In technical jargon, this permission to spend is 
referred to as "budget authority." For many programs accounted for through 
trust funds, annual appropriations are not needed. As long as their trust fund 
accounts show a balance of Federal securities, the Treasury Department has 
"budget authority" to expend funds for them.
    	Another difference between trust fund programs and other programs is 
that a trust fund account earns interest, because it contains Federal securities. 
In the case of the Social Security Trust Funds, the interest is equal to the 
prevailing average rate on outstanding Federal securities with a maturity of
4 years or longer. This interest is credited to the trust funds twice a year 
(on June 30th and December 31st) by issuing more securities to them. So in 
effect, a trust fund account can automatically build future "budget authority" 
for the program, but other accounts that depend on annual appropriations cannot.
    	Legislation enacted in 1990 (the Budget Enforcement Act, included in 
Public Law 101-508) removed Social Security taxes and benefits from calculations 
of the budget. In large part this was done to prevent Social Security from 
masking the size of Federal budget deficits and to protect it from benefit cuts 
motivated by budgetary concerns. It was based on the supposition that Congress 
would act differently in trying to reduce budget deficits if Social Security 
surpluses were not counted in reaching the budget totals (i.e., that Congress 
would ignore Social Security in devising the Nation's overall fiscal policies). 
It was not done to change where Social Security taxes go. The Federal budget 
is not a cash management account. It is simply a summary of what policymakers 
want the government's financial flows to be during any given time period. 
Whether this summary is presented in a unified or fragmented form will not in 
and of itself change how much money the government receives and spends, and it 
will not alter where Federal tax receipts of any sort go. Social Security taxes
will go into the Treasury whether or not the program is counted in the budget. 
Social Security taxes will go elsewhere only if Congress decides they will
go elsewhere.

HOW THE SOLVENCY OF THE TRUST FUNDS IS MEASURED

    	Social Security's financial condition is assessed annually by its Board 
of Trustees, composed of the Secretaries of Treasury (who is the Managing Trustee), 
Labor, Health and Human Services, as well as the Commissioner of Social Security 
and two representatives of the public. The Social Security Act requires that the 
Board of Trustees, among other duties, report to the Congress annually on the 
financial status of the Social Security Trust Funds.
	In the short range, the financial soundness of each of the trust funds 
can be assessed by considering the size of the trust fund balance in absolute 
terms, as a percentage of the annual expenditures, and with reference to whether 
the balance is growing or declining. In the long range, the traditional measure 
of financial soundness has been the actuarial balance of the system. The actuarial 
balance is defined as the difference between the total summarized income rate 
(ratio of the present value of tax income to the present value of taxable payroll 
over a 75-year period) and the total summarized cost rate (ratio of the present 
value of expenditures to the present value of taxable payroll over a 75-year 
period).
    	Because the Social Security program has been designed as a contributory 
system in which those who pay payroll taxes supporting the system are considered 
to be earning the right to future benefits, Congress has traditionally required 
long-range estimates of the program's actuarial balance and has set future tax 
rates with a view to ensuring that the income of the program will be sufficient 
to cover its outgo. Under current procedures, the long-range actuarial analysis 
of the program covers a 75-year period, which would generally be long enough to 
cover the anticipated retirement years of those currently in the work force.
    	The long-range status of the trust funds is often expressed in terms of 
percent of taxable payroll rather than in dollar amounts. This permits a direct 
comparison between the tax rate in the law and the cost of the program. For 
example, if the program is projected to have a deficit of 2 percent of taxable 
payroll, the OASDI tax rates now in the law would have to be increased by 1 
percentage point each for employee and employer (a total of 2 percent) in order 
to pay for the benefits due. Alternatively, the program could be brought back
into balance by an equivalent reduction in benefit outgo or by a combination of 
revenue increases and outgo reductions. If the program is projected to have a 
deficit of 2 percent of taxable payroll, and expenditures are projected to be 
10 percent of taxable payroll, then under the given set of assumptions, 20 percent 
(2 divided by 10) of expenditures could not be met with that tax schedule. 
In 2003, the total taxable payroll is estimated to be $4,387 billion. Thus, in 
2003 terms, 2 percent of payroll represented about $88 billion.
    	Long-range projections are affected by three basic types of factors: (1) 
demographic factors, such as rates of fertility, life expectancy, and immigration, 
which determine the number of workers in relation to beneficiaries; (2) economic 
factors such as unemployment, productivity, and inflation; and (3) factors 
specifically related to the Social Security Program, such as eligibility rules, 
benefit levels, and the categories of covered employment. The actuaries at the 
Social Security Administration (SSA) employ three sets of alternative economic and 
demographic assumptions. Alternative I is based on optimistic assumptions; 
alternative II is based on intermediate assumptions; and alternative III is 
based on pessimistic assumptions.  Alternative II is considered the "best guess" 
of long-term solvency and is the most frequently cited. It is clear that 
underlying factors cannot be predicted with any certainty as far into the future 
as 75 years. As a result, long-range projections should not be taken as absolute 
predictions of deficits or surpluses in the funds.
    	Beginning with their 1988 report, the Trustees used an alternative 
method of determining the actuarial balance.  Under this method, the actuarial 
balance for any given period is the difference between the present value of 
income and costs for the period, each divided by the present value of taxable 
payroll for the period. The present value equals the value today of the future 
tax revenue, benefit payments, and taxable payroll expected each year during the 
period, after taking into account a specified interest rate.
    	Traditionally, the Trustees based their conclusion about the long-range 
actuarial condition of the program on the "closeness" of the income and cost 
rates when averaged over a 75-year period. If the income rate was between 95 
and 105 percent of the cost rate over this projection period, the system was 
said to be in close actuarial balance. The 1991 Trustees' Report incorporated a 
more refined measure of actuarial soundness designed to reveal problems occurring 
at  any time during the 75-year measuring period. The 5-percent tolerance (i.e., 
the amount of acceptable actuarial deficit) was retained in measuring the 
program's actuarial soundness for the 75-year period as a whole, but less 
tolerance is now permitted for shorter periods of valuation.
    	The spread between income and outgo is evaluated throughout the 
measuring period in reaching a conclusion of whether close actuarial balance 
exists, with the amount of acceptable deviation gradually declining from 
5 percent for the full 75-year period to 0 (or no acceptable deviation) for 
the first 10-year segment of the measuring period.
    	To meet the short-range test of financial adequacy, the reserve balance 
at the end of the first 10-year segment must be at least 100 percent of annual 
expenditures, a condition that is consistent with the 10-year segment of the 
long-range test of close actuarial balance. The reserve balance also must be 
expected to reach that level within the first 5 years and then remain there. 
Under this revised limit, if income were at least 95 percent of the cost level 
for the 75-year period as a whole, the trust funds still could be deemed to be 
out of close actuarial balance if financial adequacy requirements are not met 
for shorter periods of valuation.
    	Under these measures, the Trustees concluded in their 2003 report, as 
they did in their twelve previous reports, that the Social Security system is 
not in close actuarial balance over the long run. Overall, for the period 
2003-77, the difference between the summarized income and cost rates for the 
OASDI Program is a deficit of 1.92 percent of taxable payroll based on the 
intermediate assumptions (Table 1-33). Therefore, on a combined basis, the 
OASDI Program is not in close actuarial balance over the next 75 years. In 
addition, the individual OASI and DI Trust Funds are not in close actuarial 
balance.
    	Income from OASDI payroll taxes represents 12.4 percent of taxable 
payroll. Because the tax rate is not scheduled to change under present law, 
OASDI payroll tax income as a percentage of taxable payroll remains constant 
at 12.4 percent. Adding the OASDI income from the income taxation of benefits 
to the income from payroll taxes yields a total "income rate" of 12.70 percent. 
This rate is estimated to increase gradually to 13.43 percent of taxable 
payroll by the end of the 75-year projection period based on the intermediate 
assumptions. The growth is attributable, in part, to increasing proportions 
in both the number of beneficiaries and the amount of their benefits subject 
to taxation in the future. These proportions will increase because the income 
thresholds, above which benefits are taxable, are fixed dollar amounts, and 
as time goes by, the incomes of more people will exceed them due to the 
expected rise in wages and prices.
    	OASDI expenditures for benefit payments and administrative expenses 
currently represent about 10.89 percent of taxable payroll. This cost rate is 
estimated to remain below the corresponding income rate for the next 15 years, 
based on the intermediate assumptions. However, with the retirement of the 76 
million members of the baby boom generation starting in about 2010, OASDI costs 
will increase rapidly relative to the taxable earnings of workers. By 2080 the 
OASDI cost rate is estimated to reach 20.09 percent under the intermediate 
assumptions, resulting in an annual deficit of 6.67 percent (Table 1-32). 
Table 1-30 shows estimated trust fund balances as a percentage of annual 
expenditures, and Tables 1-28 and 1-29 show estimated trust fund operations 
for selected calendar years 2003-40 in nominal and constant dollars, 
respectively.

FINDINGS IN LATEST TRUSTEES' REPORT

    	The Board of Trustees 2003 Report was released on March 17, 2003. The 
Congressional Budget Office (CBO) also makes Social Security projections, the 
latest of which were released in March 2003. The Trustees' projections cover a 
period of 75 years, whereas CBO's projections are only for the next 10 years. 
Both the Trustees and CBO show that through the next 10 years the favorable 
demographic pattern of a large baby boom generation at peak earning years, 
combined with the retirement of the relatively small generation born during 
the Depression, should ensure large trust fund balances. Under the Trustees' 
intermediate (or "best guess") set of assumptions, the annual excess of income 
over outlays will reach $316 billion by fiscal year 2012, and the balance of 
the trust funds will represent 4.5 years' worth of outgo. 
    	Over the long run, the projections are troubling. For a number of 
years, the Trustees' reports have projected long-range financing problems for 
the system. Although the latest report continues to show a near-term buildup 
of trust fund reserves, the intermediate forecast for the next 75 years 
shows that, on average, Social Security expenditures will be 14 percent more 
than its income. On a combined basis, the trust funds' tax revenue would fall 
short of benefit costs in 2018. Interest paid to the trust funds would allow 
the trust fund balances to keep growing until they peak at $7.5 trillion in 
nominal dollars in 2027, after which  trust fund balances would decline as 
the post-World War II baby boomers retire. 
	The Trustees estimate that by 2028 the DI Trust Fund would be 
	exhausted, and by 2044 the OASI Trust Fund would be exhausted as 
shown in Table 1-31. On a combined basis, the two trust funds would be 
exhausted in 2042. (The term "exhausted" is commonly used to indicate that 
trust fund balance plus payroll taxes and other revenues would be insufficient 
to pay all benefits when they are due.)

HISTORICAL STATUS OF THE TRUST FUNDS

    	For more than three decades after Social Security taxes were first 
levied in 1937, the system's income routinely exceeded its outgo, and its 
trust funds grew. However, the situation changed in the early 1970s. Enactment 
of major benefit increases in the 1968-72 period was followed by higher 
inflation and leaner economic conditions than had been expected. Prices rose 
faster than wages, the post-World War II baby boom ended precipitously (leading 
to a large cut in projected birth rates), and Congress adopted faulty benefit 
rules in 1972 that overcompensated new Social Security retirees for inflation. 
These factors combined to sour the outlook for Social Security and it remained 
poor through the mid-1980s.
     	Before 1971, the balances of the trust funds had never fallen below 
1 year's worth of outgo. Beginning in 1973, the program's income lagged its 
outgo, and the trust funds declined rapidly. Congress had to step in five times
during the late 1970s and early 1980s to keep them from being exhausted. 
Although majorchanges enacted in 1977 greatly reduced the program's long-run 
deficit, they did not eliminate it, and the short-run changes made by the 
legislation were not large enough to enable the program to withstand 
back-to-back recessions in 1980 and 1982. A disability bill in 1980 and 
temporary fixes in 1980 and 1981 were followed by another major reform package 
in 1983.
    	The 1983 changes, along with better economic conditions, helped alter 
the short-range picture. Income began to exceed outgo in 1983 and the trust 
funds grew substantially. Cumulatively, the changes were projected to yield 
$96 billion in surplus income by 1990, and to raise the trust funds' balances 
to $123 billion. The funds actually were credited with $200 billion in surplus 
income by 1990, and their balances reached $225 billion by the end of that year. 
By the end of fiscal year 2002, they reached $1.3 trillion. These balances 
would be equivalent to 288 percent of expenditures in 2003 (or almost 3 years' 
worth of benefits).
    	The longer range picture for Social Security has been worsening 
gradually since 1983. By gradually raising Social Security's age for receiving 
full benefits from 65 to 67, subjecting benefits to income taxes, and making 
new Federal and nonprofit workers join the system, Congress had attempted in 
1983 to eliminate the long-run problem. In fact, projections made then showed 
that Congress had stemmed the red ink, at least on average, for the following 
75 years. However, the average condition of the two trust funds did not 
represent their condition over the entire period. The funds were not shown to 
be insolvent at any point, but their expenditures were expected to exceed their 
income by 2025 and to remain higher thereafter. Simply Stated, 40 years of 
surpluses were to be followed by an indefinite period of deficits. With each 
passing year since 1983, the Trustees' 75-year averaging period has picked 
up 1 deficit year at the back end and dropped a surplus year from the front
end. This, by itself, would cause the average condition to worsen. However 
in recent reports, assumptions about birth rates, economic growth, and wages 
have been lowered, causing further deterioration in the long-term outlook.

TRENDS AFFECTING THE FINANCIAL STATUS OF THE  
SOCIAL SECURITY TRUST FUNDS

    	The 2003 Trustees' report shows an average 75-year deficit equal to 
14 percent of the program's income, and projects that the trust funds would be 
exhausted in 2042 (one year later than last year's projection). As a percent of 
the Nation's payrolls, their income would average 13.78 percent, their outgo 
15.70 percent, and the deficit would be 1.92 percent (compared to 1.87 and 
1.86 percent in the 2002 and 2001 reports respectively). This average deficit 
is slightly lower than the deficit addressed by Congress in 1983.
     	These long-range projections assume that the gross domestic product 
(GDP) (adjusted for inflation) will rise annually at rates ranging from 3.6 
percent in 2004 to 1.8 percent in 2080, wages would rise at an ultimate rate 
of 4.1 percent per year, the cost of living would go up at a rate of 3.0 percent, 
unemployment would average 5.5 percent, and that Social Security benefits would 
fall in relative terms as the age at which full benefits are payable rises 
from 65 to 67 over the 2000-22 period. The higher age for full benefits will 
mean that people retiring at age 67 or younger will get less than under the 
previous rules. These assumptions by themselves would seem to bode well for 
the system; however, looming demographic shifts are projected to overwhelm 
them. During the next fifteen years, the baby boomers will be in their prime 
productive years, and the baby-trough generation of the 1930s will be in 
retirement. Together these factors will lead to a stable ratio of workers to 
recipients. However, as the baby boomers begin retiring around 2010, this 
ratio will erode quickly. By 2025, most of the surviving baby boomers will be 
65 and older. The number of people 65 and older will have risen by 73 percent, 
growing from over 36 million today to 63 million then. The number of workers 
will have grown from 154 million to 178 million, or by only 16 percent. 
Consequently, the ratio of workers to recipients will have fallen from 
3.3 to 1 today to 2.3 to 1 in 2025 (and, by 2035, 2.1 to 1).
    	Under this forecast, the trust funds (on a combined basis) would be 
credited with surplus income through 2027 bringing their balances to a level 
of $7.5 trillion. They would decline in 2028 and thereafter, and would be 
depleted by 2042 (chart 1-1). However, tax receipts begin lagging outgo 
much sooner, in 2018. At that point, the program would have to rely on the 
interest credited to its trust funds for part of its income, which would have 
to be drawn from general revenues. In 2028, the balance of the trust funds 
would begin to be drawn down. By 2028, $1 out of every $5 of the program's 
outgo would be funded by general revenues from interest payments and the 
redemption of the government bonds in the trust funds. The government has 
never defaulted on the securities it posts to its trust funds, but the 
magnitude of these potential claims has prompted many observers to ask where 
the government will find the money to cover them. Basically, in the absence of 
surpluses for the rest of the government's operations, policymakers would have 
three options: raise other taxes, curtail other spending, or borrow money from
the financial markets. There is nothing in the law that will dictate or 
determine what they actually will (or can) do then.

Source: Board of Trustees (2003; intermediate assumptions).

    	Economists argue that if the surplus Social Security taxes projected 
for the next 15 years were to cause the government to reduce the Federal debt 
held by the public, more money would be available in the financial markets 
for investment, which could lead to greater economic growth. If this occurred,
extracting resources from the economy in the future to honor Social Security 
claims would not necessarily be as burdensome. Said another way, if one accepts 
the premise that reductions in the Federal debt held by the public today will 
increase the resources available for investment, then surplus Social Security 
taxes today could help build a higher economic base from which to draw the 
needed resources in the future.  However, running Social Security surpluses
will not by itself reduce government borrowing from the markets. Reductions 
in the debt occur when the government runs an overall or unified budget surplus, 
not when one of its programs generates surplus taxes. Even if economic growth
were enhanced in the coming decades by reductions in government debt, Social 
Security's problems would not necessarily be resolved. Further, as their 
numbers swell, the baby boomers and subsequent retirees will raise financial 
demands on other public programs for the elderly such as 
Medicare.
    	
These projections are not based on pessimistic economic assumptions. A 
modest but sustained rise in GDP and moderate inflation and unemployment are 
assumed as shown in Table 1-37. In large part, the projections hinge on 
demographic factors that are in place today--the post-World War II baby boom, 
the subsequent birth dearth, and the general aging of society. Table 1-36 shows 
how life expectancies have increased since Social Security benefits were first 
paid in 1940, and what they are projected to be in the future, as well as 
fertility and death rates. These projections suggest that to restore long-run 
solvency, Social Security program income needs to be raised or expenditures cut.

SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS AND ELIGIBILITY

BENEFIT ELIGIBILITY

    	Benefits can be paid to workers and their dependents or survivors only 
if the worker has worked long enough in covered employment to be insured for 
these benefits. Insured status is measured in terms of "credits," previously
called "quarters of coverage."  In determining whether a person has the required 
credits for insured status, Social Security uses the lifetime record of earnings 
reported under the worker's Social Security number (SSN) and counts the number of 
quarters which are covered credits.
    	Before 1978, one credit was earned for each calendar quarter in which a 
worker was paid $50 or more in wages for covered employment, or received $100 
in self-employment income.  A worker also could receive a credit for each 
multiple of $100 in annual agricultural earnings, up to a maximum of four 
credits per year. Since the beginning of 1978, the crediting of quarters of 
coverage has been on an annual rather than a quarterly basis, up to a maximum 
of four credits per year. In 

1978, a worker earned one credit (up to a maximum of four) for each $250 of 
annual earnings reported from covered employment or self-employment. The 
amount of annual earnings needed for a credit is increased each year in 
proportion to increases in average wages in the economy. In 2004 the amount 
of earnings needed for a credit is $900.  Table 1-5 shows amounts needed for 
selected calendar years, 1978-2012.
    	For the purpose of the Old-Age and Survivors Insurance (OASI) Program, 
there are two types of insured status: "fully insured" and "currently insured." 
Workers are fully insured for benefits for themselves and for their eligible 
dependents if they have total credits equaling one credit for each calendar 
year after the year they reached age 21 up to the year before they reach 
age 62, become disabled, or die, whichever occurs earlier. Fully-insured 
status is required for eligibility for all types of benefits except certain 
survivor benefits. No matter how young, a worker must have at least six 
credits to be fully insured, with the minimum number increasing with age.  
A worker with 40 credits is fully insured for life.
    	Survivors of a worker who was not fully insured may still be eligible 
for benefits if the worker was currently insured. Workers are currently insured 
if they have 6 credits during the 13 calendar quarters ending with the quarter 
in which they died.
    	Workers are insured for disability if they are fully insured and have 
a total of at least 20 credits during the 40-quarter period ending with 
the quarter in which they became disabled. Workers who are disabled 
before age 31 are insured for disability if they have credits equal to 
half the calendar quarters which have elapsed since the worker reached 
age 21, ending in the quarter in which they became 
disabled. However, a minimum of six credits is required.
    	The Personal Responsibility and Work Opportunity Reconciliation Act of 
1996 requires persons applying for Old-Age, Survivors, and Disability Insurance 
(OASDI) monthly benefits in the United States to provide evidence they are U.S. 
citizens, nationals, or aliens who are lawfully present in the United States in 
order to get Social Security benefits. To be considered a lawfully present 
alien in the United States, the beneficiary must be: lawfully admitted for 
permanent residence; admitted as a refugee under section 207 of the Immigration 
and Nationality Act (INA); granted asylum under section 208 of the INA; granted 
conditional entry as a refugee under section 203(a)(7) of the INA prior to 
April 1, 1980; an alien who has submitted an application for political asylum 
under section 208 of the INA; or an alien who belongs to any class permitted 
to reside in the United States for humanitarian or other reasons. 

Retirement benefits
    	Workers must be at least age 62 to be eligible for retirement benefits.
There is no minimum age requirement for disability benefits, but disabled 
workers who attain the full retirement age (FRA) (see later section on 
"Adjustments related to age at retirement") automatically receive full retirement 
benefits, rather than disability benefits. Disability benefits are computed as if 
the worker reached FRA on the day he became totally disabled.

Disability Benefits
    	Generally, disability is defined as the inability to engage in 
"substantial gainful activity" (SGA) by reason of a physical or mental 
impairment. The impairment must be medically determinable and expected to last 
for not less than 12 months, or to result in death.  Applicants may be determined 
to be disabled only if, due to such an impairment, they are unable to engage in 
any kind of substantial gainful work, considering their age, education, and work 
experience. The work need not exist in the immediate area in which the applicant 
lives, nor must a specific job vacancy exist for the individual. Moreover, no 
showing is required  that the worker would be hired for the job if he or she 
applied.
    	In 2004, the SGA earnings level for non-blind beneficiaries is $810 a 
month (net of impairment-related work expenses). For blind beneficiaries, the 
SGA earnings level is $1,350 a month. Both limits are indexed annually to 
average wage growth. Table 1-24 shows SGA amounts applicable since 1968.
    	An initial 5-month waiting period is required before disability insurance 
(DI) benefits are paid. Benefits are payable beginning with the sixth full month 
of disability. However, benefits may be paid for the first full month of disability 
to a worker who becomes disabled within 60 months after termination of DI benefits 
from an earlier period of disability (for a disabled widow or widower the period is 
84 months).

BENEFITS FOR THE WORKER'S FAMILY

    	Dependents' benefits are payable in addition to benefits payable to the 
worker. What follows is a review of the various types of dependents and their 
benefits.
    	Spouse's benefit.--A monthly benefit is payable to a spouse of an 
entitled retired or disabled worker under one of the following conditions: 
(1) a currently-married spouse is at least 62 or is caring for one or more of 
the worker's entitled children who are disabled or have not reached age 16; or 
(2) a divorced spouse is at least 62, is not married, and the marriage had lasted 
at least 10 years before the divorce became final. A divorced spouse may be 
entitled independently of the worker's retirement if both the worker and 
divorced spouse are age 62, and if the divorce has been final for at least 2 years.
    	Widow(er)'s benefit.--A monthly survivor benefit is payable to a widow(er) 
or divorced spouse of a worker who was fully insured at the time of death. The 
widow(er) or divorced spouse must be unmarried (unless the remarriage occurred 
after the widow(er) first became eligible for benefits as a widow(er)); and must
be either (1) age 60 or older or (2) age 50-59 and disabled throughout a waiting 
period of 5 consecutive calendar months that began no later than 7 years after 
the latest of the month the worker died, the last month of entitlement to benefits 
as a widowed mother or father, or the last month entitlement to benefits as a 
disabled widow(er) ended because the disability ended.
    	Child's benefit.--A monthly benefit is payable to a dependent, unmarried 
biological or adopted child, stepchild, or grandchild, of a retired, disabled, or 
deceased worker who was fully or currently insured at death. (To be entitled as a 
grandchild, the child's parents must be deceased or disabled.) Dependency is 
deemed for the insured's biological children and most adopted children. The child 
must be either: (1) under age 18; (2) a full-time elementary or secondary student 
under age 19; or (3) a disabled person age 18 or older whose disability began 
before age 22.
    	Mother's/father's benefit.--A monthly survivor benefit is payable to a 
mother (father) or surviving divorced mother (father) if: (1) the deceased worker 
on whose account the benefit is payable was fully or currently insured at time of 
death; and (2) the mother (father) or surviving divorced mother (father) is not 
married and has one or more entitled children of the worker in care. In the case 
of a surviving divorced mother or father, the child must also be the applicant's 
natural or legally adopted child. These payments continue as long as the youngest 
child being cared for is under age 16 or disabled (see "Child's benefit" above).
    	Parent's benefit.--A monthly survivor benefit is payable to a parent of a 
deceased fully insured worker who is age 62 or older and has not married since 
the worker's death. The parent must have been receiving at least one-half of her 
support from the worker at the time of the worker's death or, if the worker had 
a period of disability which continued until death, at the beginning of the 
period of disability.  
Proof of support must be filed within 2 years after the worker's death or the 
month in which the worker filed for disability.
    	Lump-sum death benefit.--A one-time lump-sum benefit of $255 is payable 
upon the death of a fully or currently-insured worker to the surviving spouse who 
was living with the deceased worker or was eligible to receive monthly cash 
survivor benefits upon the worker's death. If there is no eligible spouse, the 
lump-sum death benefit is payable to any child of the deceased worker who is 
eligible to receive monthly cash benefits as a surviving child. If the worker had 
no surviving spouse or children, then the lump-sum death benefit is not paid.
    	Tables 1-10 and 1-11 provide detailed information on the number of OASDI 
beneficiaries in various categories, and the average amount of monthly benefits by 
type of beneficiary.
    	Tables 1-40 and 1-41 present data on the demographic, social, and medical 
characteristics of the disabled population over time. For example, Table 1-40  
shows an increase in the receipt of disability benefits by women, reflecting 
larger societal trends in female work force participation.

BENEFIT COMPUTATION

Primary insurance amount
    	All monthly benefits are computed based on a worker's primary insurance 
amount (PIA). The PIA is a monthly amount determined by applying the Social 
Security benefit formula to a worker's average lifetime covered earnings. It is 
also the monthly benefit amount payable to a worker who retires at the full 
retirement age (FRA) or becomes entitled to disability benefits.
    	Except for workers who are eligible for a "special minimum benefit" 
(see description below), the PIA is determined through a formula applied to the 
worker's average indexed monthly earnings (AIME). The AIME is a dollar amount 
that represents the average monthly earnings from Social Security-covered 
employment over most of the worker's adult life indexed to the increase in 
average annual wages. Indexing the earnings to changes in wage levels ensures 
that the same relative value is accorded to wages, no matter when they were 
earned. Because actual average-wage data take over a year to become available, 
past earnings are updated to the second calendar year (the "indexing year") 
before the worker becomes eligible for retirement (age 62) or, if earlier, 
becomes disabled or dies. This means that the year a worker turns age 60 is 
used as the indexing year for computing retirement benefits. Earnings in and 
after the indexing year are not indexed.
    	In determining the AIME: each year's earnings prior to age 60 is 
multiplied by the ratio of the average wage for the indexing year to the average 
wage in the economy for that year; and a specific number of "computation years" 
is determined based on the number of years elapsing after 1950 (or year of 
attaining age 21, if later) up to the year the worker attains age 62, becomes 
disabled, or dies, minus any "dropout" years. The law provides for up to 5 
dropout years in retirement and survivor computations (for workers disabled 
before age 47, the number of dropout years varies from 1 to 4, depending on 
the worker's age and number of child care dropout years). The minimum number 
of computation years is 2.
    	The actual years used to compute an AIME are selected from the highest 
indexed yearly earnings in all years of earnings after 1950, up to a maximum 
of 35 years. The highest 35 years are selected in computing retirement benefits
for all workers born after 1929. The sum of the indexed earnings in the selected
years is divided by the number of months in the computation period (i.e., the 
number of the selected years times 12) to determine the AIME.
    	The indexed earnings histories (rounded to whole dollars) are 
illustrated in Table 1-15 for four hypothetical workers retiring in 2003 at 
age 62. The actual earnings for the four workers are shown in columns 4 through 7. 
These are multiplied by the ratio of the average wage index in the indexing year 
to the average wage index in the year of earnings to arrive at the indexed earnings 
(last 4 columns). The indexing year is the year in which the worker attains age 60. 
For years after the indexing year, an indexing ratio of 1.0 is used.  The highest 
35 years of indexed earnings are used to determine the worker's PIA. For example, 
a full-time worker who had maximum creditable earnings from ages 22 through 61 
would drop low earnings in 1963, 1964, 1965, 1970 and 1971, and would have total 
indexed earnings of $2,406,351. Dividing total indexed earnings by the number of 
months in the computation period (35 years times 12 months = 420 months) results 
in AIME of 5,729. The corresponding AIMEs for the low, medium and high earners 
are $1,234, $2,744 and $4,343, respectively. Low earners are defined as workers 
with scaled earnings that average over their career to about 45 percent of the 
average wage; medium earners are defined as workers with scaled earnings that 
average over their career to about the average wage; high earners are defined as 
workers with scaled earnings that average over their career to about160 percent of 
the average wage; and maximum earners are defined as workers who earn the 
Social Security maximum taxable earnings base throughout their career.
    	The PIA is determined by applying the primary benefit formula to the AIME. 
For a maximum-wage worker becoming eligible in 2003, the PIA is determined as 
follows:

  
  
  
  	Applying this formula to the AIMEs of the four hypothetical workers 
results in PIAs of $746.30 for the low-wage worker, $1,229.50 for the average-wage 
worker, $1,623.90 for the high-wage worker and $1,831.80 for the maximum-wage 
worker. (For the low-wage worker, the 2003 special minimum benefit (see below) 
PIA of $625.60 is less than the AIME-based PIA of $746.30,and therefore is not 
used to determine her benefits.) The numbers $606 and $3,653 are often referred  
to as "bend points" of the PIA formula. These amounts are adjusted each year by 
the change in average wages. After the year of initial eligibility (age 62 for 
retired workers), the PIA is increased each year for the increase in the Consumer 
Price Index (CPI). The PIAs of $746.30, $1,229.50, $1,623.90 and $1,831.80 would 
be in effect for January through November 2003, and will be increased by the 
cost-of-living adjustment (COLA) effective beginning December 2003 (see    
section on COLAs below). The PIA is recomputed after each year that an entitled 
worker has earnings that may lead to a higher benefit.
    	Other methods for determining a PIA also exist, and PIAs based on different 
methods must be compared to select the highest one, which is used to determine the 
worker's benefits. The most common of these other methods is the one used to 
determine the special minimum PIA. This PIA is designed to assist workers with 
long-term low earnings.
    	The monthly benefit amount payable to a disabled worker under the FRA, or 
to a retired worker who first receives benefits at the FRA, is the PIA rounded to 
the next lower dollar, if not already a multiple of $1. Auxiliary benefit amounts 
are also based on the worker's PIA. Table 1-12 lists major types of auxiliary 
benefits and the percent of the insured worker's PIA that is applicable to benefits 
paid at the full rate, unreduced for early election of retirement.
    	Special minimum benefit.--The special minimum benefit is not based on the 
amount of a worker's average earnings, but instead on his number of years of 
covered employment. It is structured to provide a larger benefit than would 
otherwise be payable to those who worked in covered employment for many years 
but had low earnings. The amount of the special minimum is computed by 
multiplying the number of years of coverage in excess of 10 years and up to 30 
years by $11.50 for monthly benefits payable in 1979, with automatic cost-of-living 
increases applicable to years 1979 and later. The number of years of coverage for 
the purpose of qualifying for a special minimum benefit equals the number obtained 
by dividing total creditable wages in 1937-50 by $900 (not to exceed 14), plus the 
number of years after 1950 and before 1991 for which the worker is credited with at 
least 25 percent of the annual maximum taxable earnings. For this purpose, for 
years after 1978, annual maximum taxable earnings are defined as the "old-law" 
taxable earnings base (i.e., the hypothetical earnings base that would be in effect 
if the ad hoc increases in the base enacted in 1977 were disregarded). In addition, 
for years after 1990, a year of coverage is earned if the worker is credited with 
at least 15 percent of the "old-law" taxable earnings base. The special minimum 
benefit is not subject to the delayed retirement credit provisions described earlier.

Cost-of-living adjustments
    	As a result of the Social Security Amendments of 1972, monthly cash 
benefits are automatically adjusted for inflation each year to maintain the 
purchasing power of benefits over time. Prior to the 1972 amendments, monthly 
cash benefits were increased on an ad hoc basis 10 times. Automatic annual 
cost-of-living adjustments (COLAs) have been provided since 1975, except during 
calendar year 1983 when the adjustment was delayed 6 months. Table 1-18 shows 
Social Security benefit increases from the beginning of the program through 
January 2003.  (The first COLA was paid in October 1950).
    	Under section 215(i) of the Social Security Act, COLAs are indexed to 
changes in the Consumer Price Index for Urban Wage Earners and Clerical 
Workers (CPI-W) published by the Bureau of Labor Statistics, Department of 
Labor. Social Security COLAs are based on the percentage change in the average 
CPI-W for the third quarter of the previous year to the third quarter of the 
current year. The COLA becomes effective in December of the current year and is 
payable in January of the following year (the Social Security check received in 
January reflects the benefit payment for December). The 2.1 percent COLA 
effective in December 2003 (payable in January 2004) is computed as follows:





    	Since 1975, the Social Security COLA triggers identical percentage 
increases in Supplemental Security Income (SSI), veterans pensions, and railroad 
retirement benefits, and causes other changes in the Social Security Program. 
Although COLAs under the Federal Civil Service Retirement System (CSRS) and 
the Federal Military Retirement Program are not triggered by the Social Security 
COLA, these programs use the same measuring period and formula for computing 
their COLAs. Table 1-19 compares average wage increases, increases in the 
average annual CPI-W, and benefit increases from 1965 to 2002. 

Adjustments related to age at retirement
    	Reduction for early retirement.--Benefits for retired workers, aged 
spouses, and widow(er)s taken before the FRA are subject to an actuarial 
reduction, such that over their lifetimes on average they receive the same 
aggregate benefits as someone who retires later. The FRA is the earliest age 
at which unreduced retirement benefits can be received. The FRA is gradually 
rising in two steps beginning with people born in 1938. First, for workers and 
their spouses, the FRA will increase by 2 months for each year that a person 
is born after 1937, until it reaches age 66 for persons born in 1943. The FRA 
will remain age 66 for persons born from 1943 to 1954.  Second, it will increase 
again by 2 months for each year that a person is born after 1954, until it 
reaches age 67 for those who were born after 1959. For widow(er)s, the increase 
to age 67 will be phased in similarly, but will begin for persons born after 1935.  
Early retirement still will be available, but benefits will be lower. The 
actuarial reduction on retirement benefits at age 62 ultimately will be 
30 percent, instead of the present 20 percent.
    	Delayed retirement credits.--Benefits of workers who choose to retire 
after their FRA are increased by delayed retirement credits, as are the benefits 
payable to their widow(er)s. The delayed retirement credit was 1 percent per year 
for workers who attained age 65 before 1982, and 3 percent per year for workers 
who attained age 65 between 1982 and 1989. Starting in 1990, the delayed retirement 
credit has been increasing by one-half of 1 percent every other year until it 
reaches 8 percent for workers reaching age 65 after 2007. Table 1-20 shows the 
schedule of increases in the FRA and adjustments related to a worker's age at 
the time he elects to receive 
benefits.
    	Table 1-14 shows the percentage of workers electing to receive retirement 
benefits at various ages since the beginning of the Social Security Program. The 
data illustrate a trend toward early retirement in the 1960-85 period.  Since that 
time, the trend has generally leveled out. For the past two decades, the average 
age (combined average for men and women) at which workers elect retirement 
benefits has hovered around the current average age of 63.6. Recently, the 
average age at which women elect to receive retirement benefits has turned upward. 
Table 1-13 shows the number and percentage of retired workers electing reduced 
benefits since they first became available (totals for men and women are shown 
separately).

Adjustments for multiple beneficiaries
    	Maximum family benefit.--A maximum family benefit is payable based on a 
worker's PIA. For benefits payable on the earnings records of retired and deceased 
workers, the maximum varies from 150 to 188 percent of the PIA.  The family 
maximum cannot be exceeded regardless of the number of recipients entitled on 
that earnings record. The family maximum is computed by adding fixed 
percentages of dollar amounts that are part of the PIA.  For the family of a worker 
who turns 62 or dies in 2003 before attaining age 62, the total amount of benefits 
payable is limited to:

150 percent of the first $774 of PIA; plus
272 percent of PIA over $774 through $1,118; plus
134 percent of PIA over $1,118 through $1,458; plus
175 percent of PIA over $1,458.

	The dollar amounts in this benefit formula (i.e., the "bend points") are 
indexed to average wage growth as in the primary benefit formula.
    	Whenever the total of the individual monthly benefits payable to all 
recipients entitled on one earnings record exceeds the maximum, each dependent's 
or survivor's benefit is reduced in equal proportion to bring the total within the 
maximum. In computing the maximum family benefit, any benefit payable to a 
divorced spouse or to a surviving divorced spouse is not included.
    	For the family of a worker who is entitled to disability benefits, the 
maximum family benefit is the smaller of 85 percent of the worker's AIME, or 150 
percent of the worker's PIA. However, in no case can the benefit be less than 100 
percent of the worker's PIA.

Adjustments related to earnings and other benefits
    	Earnings limit.--The earnings limit is a provision in the law that reduces 
benefits for nondisabled recipients under the FRA who earn income from work in 
excess of a certain sum (the "exempt" amount).
    	The earnings limit was part of the original plan that led to Social 
Security. The 1935 report of the Committee on Economic Security appointed by 
President Franklin D. Roosevelt recommended that no benefits be paid before a 
person had "retired from gainful employment." Initially, the Social Security Act
provided that benefits would not be paid for any month in which the individual 
had received "wages with respect to regular employment."
    	The earnings limit has been changed many times over the years. Effective 
in 2000, it no longer applies to individuals when they attain the FRA. For 
recipients below the FRA, the law provides that recipients who will not attain 
the FRA in that year may earn up to $11,640 (in 2004) in annual wages or self-
employment income without having their benefits affected. For earnings above 
these amounts, recipients lose $1 of benefits for each $2 of excess earnings. 
There is a different reduction factor and exempt amount in the year recipients
attain the FRA. In 2004, these individuals can earn up to $31,080 a year in the 
months before they attain the FRA. 
 For earnings above these amounts, they lose $1 in benefits for each $3 of excess 
earnings. The exempt amounts rise each year at the same rate as average wages in 
the economy. The test does not apply to recipients at the FRA or older, or to 
those who are disabled (who are subject to separate limits on earnings known as 
substantial gainful activity or SGA). In December 2001, 136,788 recipients had
all of their benefits withheld because of the earnings limit.
    	Retired workers whose benefits are not paid due to the earnings limit 
for one or more months are compensated through future increases in their 
benefit amount because their actuarial reduction factor is lowered.


Example of effect of the earnings limit: John-age 63 with $8,000 in annual 
benefits before the earnings limit is applied:

Earnings in 2004                	          $12,640
Exempt amount for under FRA	                   11,640

Excess over exempt amount	                    1,000
Benefit reduction = 50 percent of excess              500
Benefits John will receive in 2004	            7,500

    	The earnings limit does not apply to pensions, rents, dividends, interest, 
and other types of "unearned" income. These forms of income always have been 
exempted in order to encourage savings for retirement to supplement Social 
Security.
    	Of 10 million recipients entitled to retired worker benefits who were 
under the age of 70 in 2000, about 3 million had earnings from work. Table 1-23 
shows the distribution of the earnings of these workers.
    	Dual entitlement.--An individual may be entitled to benefits both as a 
worker, based on his or her own earnings, and also as a dependent (spouse or 
widow(er)) of another worker. In this case, the individual does not collect the 
full amount of both benefits. The amount of the benefit payable as a spouse or 
widow(er) is offset dollar for dollar by the amount of any benefit the individual 
is entitled to as a worker. In other words, workers first receive the benefit 
based on their work record. A dependent benefit is only payable if it is higher 
than the benefit based on the spouse's own work. The dependent benefit equals the 
difference between the full spouse benefit and the benefit based on the spouse's 
own work.
    	Government pension offset.--Social Security benefits payable to spouses of 
retired, disabled, or deceased workers are generally reduced to take account of any 
public pension the spouse receives as a result of work in a government job (Federal, 
State, or local) not covered by Social Security. The amount of the reduction is 
equal to two-thirds of the government pension. This provision is intended to place 
spouses who worked in jobs not covered by Social Security in a position similar to 
other workers by applying the equivalent of the Social Security "dual entitlement" 
rule, which imposes a dollar-for-dollar offset of spouses' benefits (discussed 
above). Two-thirds of the government pension represents an approximation of the 
Social Security worker's benefit that would be subtracted from any Social Security 
spousal benefit. The offset does not apply to workers whose government job is 
covered by Social Security on the last day of the person's employment.
    	Generally, Federal workers hired before 1984 are part of the Civil Service 
Retirement System (CSRS) and are not covered by Social Security.  Federal 
workers hired after 1983 are covered by the Federal Employee's Retirement System 
Act of 1986 (FERS), which includes coverage by Social Security. Employees 
covered by the CSRS were given opportunities in 1987 and 1998 to join FERS and 
thereby obtain Social Security coverage. Workers who switched from CSRS to 
FERS must have at least 5 years of FERS coverage to be exempt from the 
government pension offset.
    	Windfall elimination provision.--The Social Security Amendments of 1983 
included a provision known as the windfall elimination provision. Under this 
provision, the benefits of workers who also have pensions from work that was not 
covered by Social Security are calculated using a different formula designed to 
equalize the rate at which Social Security replaces their career earnings that were 
covered by Social Security with those of workers who had all their work covered  
by Social Security. 
	Social Security's benefit formula is designed to help keep people out of 
poverty by replacing more of low-wage worker's career earnings than higher-wage 
workers. However, if a job is not covered by Social Security, the formula records 
"zero" earnings for that year. If a person had many years of "zero" earnings 
averaged into the benefit formula, they would appear to have low earnings during 
their work career when that was not the case. Before the law was changed, workers 
who were employed for only a portion of their careers in jobs covered by Social 
Security received an unintended "windfall" because their benefits replaced more of 
their pre-retirement wages compared to identical workers who were covered by 
Social Security their entire careers. This happened because many years of "zero" 
earnings were recorded for the jobs not covered under Social Security, making the 
public employee appear to have low lifetime earnings.
    	The windfall benefit formula is intended to remove this unintentional 
advantage for these workers. It does so by substituting 40 percent for the 90 
percent factor in the first bracket of the  benefit formula (see discussion in 
earlier section on "Benefit Computation"). The resulting reduction in the worker's 
Social Security benefit is limited to one-half the amount of the non-covered 
pension. The new law was phased in over a 5-year period and affects those first 
eligible for both Social Security benefits and non-covered pensions after 1985.
    	Workers who have 30 years or more of substantial Social Security covered 
earnings are fully exempt from this provision. For workers who have 21-29 years of 
substantial covered earnings, the percentage in the first bracket in the formula 
increases by 5 percentage points for each year over 20, as shown in Table 1-21.
    	Offset for other public disability benefits.--When a worker receiving 
Social Security disability benefits also qualifies for other disability benefits 
that are provided by Federal, State or local governments or worker's compensation, 
any Social Security benefits payable to the worker and his family are reduced by 
the amount, if any, that the total monthly benefits payable under the two or more 
programs exceed 80 percent of average current earnings before the worker became 
disabled. Needs-tested benefits, Veterans Administration disability benefits, and 
benefits based on public employment covered by Social Security are not subject to 
the reduction. A worker's average current earnings for this purpose are the largest 
of: (1) the average monthly earnings used for computing Social Security benefits; 
(2) the average monthly earnings in employment or self-employment covered by 
Social Security during the 5 consecutive years of highest covered earnings after 
1950; or (3) the average monthly earnings for the calendar year of highest covered 
earnings during the year disability began and the preceding 5 years (based on total 
earnings, not limited to maximum taxable earnings). The combined payments after 
the reduction are never less than the total amount of the DI benefits payable before 
the reduction. In addition, the Social Security benefit after the reduction is 
increased by the full amount of the cost-of-living increase as applied to the 
unreduced benefit. Every 3 years the original amount of benefits subject to 
reduction is redetermined to reflect changes in average wage levels. If increases 
in average national wages would result in a higher benefit than that payable based 
on the original computation, the benefit is increased effective in January of the 
redetermination year.
    	The reduction begins in the month during which concurrent entitlement 
begins under a Federal or State law. However, the offset will not be made if the 
State workers' compensation law provides for an offset against Social Security 
disability benefits and was in effect as of February 18, 1981.
Suspension of benefits to prisoners
    	In 1980, legislation was enacted barring payment of disability benefits to 
prisoners who committed felonies (Public Law 96-473).  In 1983, the prohibition 
was broadened to include retirement and survivor benefits (Public Law 98-21); and 
in 1994, payment of benefits was barred to those in public institutions who 
committed serious crimes, but who were found incompetent to stand trial, or not 
guilty by reason of insanity (Public Law 103-387). Only benefits to the prisoner are 
barred; benefits to a prisoner's eligible spouse and children are payable.
    	The Ticket to Work and Work Incentives Improvement Act of 1999 (Public 
Law 106-170) further revised the bar on OASDI benefits to include prisoners who 
are convicted of a criminal offense and are confined (for more than 30 days) to 
(1) a penal institution; (2) a public institution if found guilty but insane; or 
(3) a public institution upon completion of a prison term for a sex offense, 
pursuant to a court finding that they remain a danger to others. It also provided 
for incentive payments of up to $400 to State and local institutions for each 
Social Security beneficiary found ineligible because of their incarceration.

TAXATION OF BENEFITS

    	Beneficiaries with income (defined as adjusted gross income plus tax-exempt 
bond interest plus one-half of Social Security benefits) above certain thresholds 
are required to include a portion of their Social Security benefits (and railroad 
retirement tier 1 benefits) in their Federally taxable income. The Social Security 
Amendments of 1983 required beneficiaries with income of more than $25,000 if 
single, and $32,000 if married filing jointly, to include up to 50 percent of their 
benefits in their taxable income, beginning in 1984.  Revenues from this provision 
are credited to the OASDI Trust Funds. The Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of 
1993 required beneficiaries with incomes of more than $34,000 if single, and 
$44,000 if married filing jointly, to include up to 85 percent of their benefits in 
their taxable income, beginning in 1994. Revenues from this provision are credited 
to the Medicare Hospital Insurance (HI) Trust Fund. (There is no separate threshold 
for married persons who live together and file separately.)
    	These income thresholds are specified in the law. By design, they are not 
indexed to wage growth. Thus over time, an increasing number of individuals will 
be subject to the income tax on Social Security benefits. When the first tier of 
benefit taxation was enacted in 1983, the Social Security Trust Funds faced almost 
immediate insolvency. Fixed thresholds were established to provide the program 
with a growing source of revenue from the income tax on benefits to help shore up 
the Social Security Trust Funds. When taxes on benefits were first imposed, 8 
percent of recipients were affected. As shown in Table 1-25, the Congressional 
Budget Office (CBO) estimates that under 2003 law (simulated using 2000 
population and incomes), 39 percent of recipients had some benefits taxed .  Table 
1-26 shows amounts credited to the trust funds from the taxation of benefits. Table 
1-27 provides a worksheet for determining the taxable portion of Social Security 
benefits.  Examples of the effects of the taxation of benefits are shown below:



DISABILITY DETERMINATION AND THE CLAIMS PROCESS

The Claims Process
    	The Social Security claims process is a complex multilayered structure that 
is inextricably linked with the disability determination process. Application for 
disability benefits is made at the Social Security field office where the applicant 
is interviewed and the sources of medical evidence are recorded. After determining 
whether the applicant meets the insured status requirements, the SSA field office 
sends the case to the State Disability Determination Service (DDS), which makes 
the initial determination of disability. If an applicant or beneficiary is 
dissatisfied with an initial denial or termination of disability benefits by the 
DDS, she can request a reconsideration within 60 days of receipt of the notice of 
denial. The reconsideration on the disability claim is carried out by DDS by 
personnel other than those who made the initial determination.
    	An applicant denied benefits at the reconsideration stage may request a 
hearing before an administrative law judge (ALJ) in SSA's Office of Hearings and 
Appeals, provided he files a request for a hearing within 60 days of receipt of 
the notice of denial. If the claim is denied by the ALJ, the applicant has 60 days 
to request review by the Appeals Council. The Appeals Council is a 24-member body 
located in the Office of Hearings and Appeals. The Appeals Council may also, on 
its own motion, review a decision within 60 days of the ALJ's decision. The 1980 
disability amendments required the Appeals Council to review a percentage of ALJ 
hearing decisions.
    	The Appeals Council may affirm, modify, or reverse the decision of the ALJ, 
or may remand it to the ALJ for further development.  The applicant is notified in 
writing of the final action of the Appeals Council and his right to obtain further 
review by commencing a civil action within 60 days in a U.S. District Court.
    	Under current law, as amended by the 1984 Disability Benefits Reform Act, 
disability insurance (DI) beneficiaries whose benefits have been terminated because 
of recovery or improvement in the medical condition that was the basis for the 
disability have the opportunity to receive a hearing at the reconsideration stage 
and can elect to continue to receive disability and Medicare benefits through the 
ALJ hearing stage of the appeals process, subject to repayment if the individual 
is ultimately found not disabled.
    	Chart 1-2 shows the number of cases allowed and appealed at various 
decision levels for claim applications and continuing disability reviews (CDRs) 
processed by State agencies. Table 1-43 presents information for fiscal years 
1980-2002 on the number of cases that were reviewed and reversed at the ALJ 
level. Table 1-44 presents information on the number of CDRs that were conducted 
in fiscal years 1977-2001 on DI cases. Due to an unprecedented increase in initial 
claims, the number of CDRs processed declined sharply in the early 1990s. 
National implementation of a new review process in 1993 has enabled the Social 
Security Administration to increase the number of CDRs significantly.
    	State agencies, which are 100 percent Federally funded, generally  make 
disability decisions. These agencies agree to make such determinations, and in 
doing so to substantially comply with the regulations of the Commissioner that 
specify performance standards, administrative requirements, and procedures to be 
followed in performing the disability determination function.
    	The law authorizes the Commissioner to terminate State administration and 
assume responsibility for making disability determinations when a State DDS is 
substantially failing to make determinations consistent with regulations. The law 
also allows for termination by the State.
      	Claims are determined on a sequential basis. The first step is to 
determine whether the individual is engaging in SGA. Under current regulations, 
in most cases if a nonblind person is earning more than $810 a month (net of 
impairment-related work expenses) in 2004, he will be considered to be engaging in 
SGA. In the case of blind individuals, SGA is $1,350 a month in 2004. If it is 
determined that the individual is engaging in SGA, a decision is made that she is 
not disabled without considering medical factors. If an individual is found not to 
be engaging in SGA, the severity and duration of the impairment are explored. If 
the impairment is determined to be "not severe" (i.e., it does not significantly 
limit the individual's capacity to perform basic work activities), the individual's 
disability claim is denied. If the impairment is "severe," a determination is 
made as to whether the impairment "meets" or "equals" the medical listings 
published in regulations by SSA,  and whether it will last for 12 months. If the 
impairment neither "meets" nor "equals" the listing (which would result in an 
allowance), but meets the 12-month duration rule, the individual's residual 
functional capacity (what an individual still can do despite his limitations) 
and the physical and mental demands of past relevant work must be evaluated. 
If the impairment does not prevent the individual from meeting the demands of 
past relevant work, benefits are denied. If the impairment does, then it must 
be determined whether the impairment prevents other work.

CHART 1-2-DISABILITY DETERMINATIONS AND APPEALS,  
FISCAL YEAR 2002




    	At this stage in the adjudication process, because of a court decision 
and subsequent administrative and legislative ratification of this decision, the 
burden of proof switches to the government to show that the individual can, 
considering her impairment, age, education, and work experience, engage in some 
other kind of SGA that exists in the national economy. Such work does not have 
to exist in the immediate area in which he lives, and a specific job vacancy does 
not have to be available to him. Work in the national economy is defined in 
statute as work which exists in significant numbers either in the region where 
such individual lives or in several regions of the country.
    	SSA has developed a vocational "grid" designed to reduce the subjectivity 
and lack of uniformity in applying the vocational factor. Through a formula, the 
grid regulations relate certain worker characteristics such as age, education, 
and past work experience to the individual's residual functional capacity to 
perform work-related physical and mental activities. If the applicant has a 
particular level of residual work capability--characterized by the terms sedentary, 
light, medium, heavy and very heavy--an automatic finding of "disabled" or "not
disabled" is required when such capability is applied to various combinations of 
age, education, and work experience.
    	The Commissioner must review 50 percent of the disability allowances and a 
sufficient number of other determinations to ensure a high degree of accuracy.  The 
Commissioner may also, on her own initiative, review any determination by a DDS.
    	The 1980 disability amendments required that, at least once every 3 years, 
the Social Security Administration reexamine every individual on the rolls who is 
determined to be non-permanently disabled.  Where there is a finding of permanent 
disability, the Commissioner may reexamine the individual at such times as are 
determined to be appropriate. These reviews are in addition to the administrative 
eligibility review procedures existing before the 1980 amendments. Effective in 
2001, these reviews cannot begin while an individual is "using a ticket" as defined 
by the Commissioner (see "Changes in the 106th Congress" below).
    	The 1984 Disability Benefits Reform Act required that in continuing 
eligibility review cases, benefits may be terminated only if the Commissioner finds 
that there has been medical improvement in the person's condition and that the 
individual is now able to engage in SGA.
    	Individuals are not considered to be disabled unless they furnish such 
medical and other evidence as the Commissioner may require. The Commissioner 
will generally reimburse physicians or hospitals for supplying medical evidence in 
support of claims for DI benefits. The Commissioner also pays for medical 
examinations that are needed to adjudicate the claim.
    	Representation and attorneys' fees.--Claimants may appoint an attorney or 
any other qualified person to serve as their representative in proceedings before 
SSA. The representative may submit evidence, make statements about facts and 
law, and make any request or give any notice concerning the proceedings. The 
representative may not sign an application on behalf of a claimant for rights or 
benefits, or testify on the claimant's behalf in any administrative proceeding.
    	The amount of any fee that an attorney or other person may charge and 
collect from the claimant for services performed as a representative must be 
authorized by SSA. SSA has two methods of authorizing fees for representation: 
fee petition and fee agreement.
    	Under the fee petition process, representatives must promptly file a fee 
petition with SSA after completing their services on a claim and send a copy of 
the fee petition to the claimant. SSA determines the amount of the fee authorized 
under the fee petition process based on several factors, including, but not limited 
to, the extent and type of services the representative performed, the complexity of 
the case, and the amount of time the representative spent on the case.
    	Under the fee agreement process, the claimant and representative must 
file a written agreement with SSA before the date SSA makes a favorable 
determination or decision on the claim. SSA usually will approve the fee agreement 
if: (1) it is signed by both the claimant and representative; (2) the fee 
specified in the agreement does not exceed the lesser of 25 percent of the 
past-due benefits or $5,300 for fee agreements approved on or after February 1, 
2002 (for fee agreements approved before that date, the maximum dollar limit was 
$4,000); (3) SSA's determination or decision in the claim is fully or partially 
favorable; and (4) the claim results in past-due benefits.  
	If the claimant is represented by an attorney and the claim is for Social 
Security benefits, the SSA may withhold the authorized representation fee out of 
past-due benefits and pay it directly to the attorney. SSA assumes no 
responsibility for the payment of any fees if the representative is not an 
attorney or the claim is for SSI benefits.
    	The Ticket to Work and Work Incentives Improvement Act of 1999 (Public 
Law 106-170, signed December 17, 1999) requires the Commissioner to impose an 
assessment on the attorney's fee to cover SSA's costs of determining and certifying 
these fees. Effective January 31, 2000, the assessment is set at 6.3 percent of the 
attorney's fee. For years after 2000, the percentage rate will be set at a level 
determined by the Commissioner to achieve full recovery of the costs of 
calculating, withholding, and paying fees from the claimant's past-due benefits, but 
not in excess of 6.3 percent.  The attorney is prohibited from recovering this 
assessment from the claimant.

Work incentives
    	The law provides a 45-month period for disabled beneficiaries to test their 
ability to work without losing their entitlement to all benefits. The period consists 
of: (1) a "trial work period" (TWP), which allows disabled beneficiaries to work for 
up to 9 months (within any 60-month period  with no effect on their disability or 
Medicare benefits; followed by (2) a 36-month "extended period of eligibility," of 
which during the last 33 months cash disability benefits are suspended for any 
month in which the individual is engaged in SGA. 
	Medicare coverage continues for 102 months once work activity begins (the 
duration of the trial work period and the extended period of eligibility, plus an 
additional 54 months) as long as the individual continues to remain medically 
disabled. When Medicare entitlement ends because of the individual's work 
activity, if he is still medically disabled, he may purchase Medicare protection.
    	If beneficiaries medically recover to the extent that they no longer meet the 
definition of disability, both disability and Medicare benefits are terminated after 
3 months, regardless of the status of the TWP or extended period of eligibility. 
However, a person who contests this determination may elect to continue to receive 
disability benefits (subject to repayment) and Medicare while the appeal is being 
reviewed. 

Return to work and rehabilitation
    	Public Law 106-170 created a Ticket to Work and Self-Sufficiency Program 
to help disability beneficiaries access a broader pool of vocational rehabilitation 
providers to enable them to achieve self-sufficiency. Under this legislation, the 
Commissioner of Social Security provides tickets to work to disability beneficiaries 
that can be used as vouchers to obtain employment services, case management, 
vocational rehabilitation, and support services under an individual work plan from 
the provider of their choice, including the State vocational rehabilitation agencies. 
Payments to the providers entering agreements with SSA are based on employment 
outcomes and long-term results or on a combination of milestones and outcomes, 
and come from a portion of the benefits forgone by beneficiaries when they return 
to work. The program is being implemented in selected sites beginning 1 year after 
enactment, with services available in every State within 4 years of enactment.
    	Until the Ticket to Work and Self-Sufficiency Program is fully implemented 
and for States that elect to not participate in this program, provisions remain in 
effect that allow for reimbursement from the DI Trust Funds to the State vocational 
rehabilitation agencies for rehabilitation services that result in the beneficiary's 
performance of SGA for a continuous period of at least 9 months.  Such a 9-month 
period could begin while the individual is under a vocational rehabilitation program 
and may coincide with the TWP or the individual's waiting period for benefits. The 
services must be performed under a State plan for vocational rehabilitation services 
under title I of the Vocational Rehabilitation Act. In 1996, SSA established by 
regulations an Alternative Rehabilitation Provider Program which allows SSA to 
refer beneficiaries to private vocational rehabilitation providers and public 
non-State vocational rehabilitation providers if SSA does not receive notification 
within a specified period that the State agency has accepted a beneficiary for 
services or extended evaluation.
    	In addition, beneficiaries participating in the Ticket to Work and 
Self-Sufficiency Program will not be subject to unscheduled CDRs triggered by 
their work activities.  For certain former beneficiaries whose entitlement to 
benefits ended solely because of their earnings from work, the Ticket to Work law 
provides for swift reinstatement of benefits without requiring a new application. 
(For more information on the Ticket to Work and Self-Sufficiency Program, refer to 
Section 3: Supplemental Security Income.) 

Enrollment and applicant backlogs
    	Over the past 20 years, the DI Program experienced a period of declining 
enrollment followed by a rebound in growth.  The number of DI beneficiaries 
(disabled workers and their dependents) receiving benefits first peaked at 4.9 
million in May 1978. The beneficiary population then declined sharply to 3.8 
million by July 1984. Thereafter, the number of beneficiaries has risen steadily, 
reaching 7.2 million in December 2002 (Table 1-39).
    	Similarly, the number of new DI benefit awards declined from 592,000 in 
1975 to approximately 297,000 in 1982. As shown in Table 1-42, awards then rose 
almost steadily, reaching 646,000 in 1995 before declining by 1997 to 588,000.  
In 2002 there were 750,000 new DI benefit awards. (The large 1992 increase is 
partially attributable to SSA's short-term measures for dealing with increased 
DI applications. Increasing the volume of applications processed resulted in 
increases in both awards and denials.) The incidence of disability (number of 
awards per 1,000 insured workers) fell from an all-time high of 7.1 in 1975 to 
an all-time low of 2.9 in 1982. In 2002, the rate was 5.3 percent (Table 1-42).
    	Pending claims at DDS, hearings and appeals levels.--Until fiscal year 
1991, disability claims (including initial claims, reconsiderations, hearings 
and appeals) remained relatively constant at about 2.5 million cases per year.  
In fiscal year 1991, claims began to increase significantly each year and reached 
3.7 million in fiscal year 1996. In fiscal year 2001, there were over 3.4 million 
disability claims. 
During the period of fiscal years 1988-94, the number of cases pending at the 
State DDS also increased as the ability to hire and train DDS staff did not keep 
pace with the increases in claims. However, in fiscal year 1995 pending cases were 
significantly reduced to 590,000 due largely to increased productivity in the 
State DDSs and the additional budgetary resources directed to disability case 
processing which enabled an aggressive hiring effort in the States.  In fiscal
year 1996, pending cases again increased significantly. The major cause of this 
increase was that Congress increased SSA's workload by requiring additional 
drug addiction and alcoholism reviews. These reviews now have been completed, 
but pending cases have risen again due to workloads mandated by other welfare 
reform legislation (Table 1-45).

SOCIAL SECURITY'S TREATMENT IN THE FEDERAL BUDGET

SOCIAL SECURITY'S OFF-BUDGET STATUS

    	Under an administrative action by President Johnson, Social Security and 
other Federal programs that operate through trust funds were counted officially in 
the budget beginning in fiscal year 1969. At the time, the Old-Age, Survivors, and 
Disability Insurance (OASDI) Trust Funds were running a surplus while the 
remainder of the Federal budget was running a deficit that reflected the 
increasing costs of the war in Vietnam. At the time, Congress did not have its 
own formal budget-making process with statutory rules, restrictions on taxes 
and spending, and its own budget estimating office. In 1974, with passage of the 
Congressional Budget and Impoundment Control Act (Public Law 93-344), Congress 
adopted procedures for setting budget goals through passage of annual budget 
resolutions. Like the budgets prepared by the President, these resolutions were
to reflect a "unified" budget that included trust fund programs such as Social 
Security.

Financial problems confronting Social Security and concern over its growing 
costs led to enactment of a number of benefit changes in 1977, 1980, 1981, and 
1983.  Measures were enacted in 1983, 1985, and 1987 making the program a more 
distinct part of the budget and permitting floor objections (points of order) to be 
raised against budget bills containing Social Security changes.
    	Later in the 1980s, when Social Security surpluses emerged, critics argued 
that the program was masking the size of Federal budget deficits.  In response, 
Congress in 1990 excluded Social Security from calculations of the budget and 
largely exempted it from procedures for controlling spending (Omnibus Budget 
Reconciliation Act of 1990, Public Law 101-508). By these actions, however, 
Congress excluded Social Security from procedural constraints designed to 
discourage measures that would increase deficits. Concerned that this change would 
encourage Social Security spending increases and tax cuts that could weaken Social 
Security's financial condition, Congress also included provisions permitting floor 
objections to be raised against bills that would erode the balances of the Social 
Security Trust Funds.
    
BUDGETARY TREATMENT OF ADMINISTRATIVE EXPENSES

    	The costs of administering the Social Security Retirement and Disability 
Programs are financed from the Social Security Trust Funds, subject to annual 
appropriations. Traditionally these costs are low, now comprising less than 1 
percent of annual benefit payments. During fiscal year 2002, they amounted to $4.1 
billion (Table 1-38).
    	These trust-fund-financed administrative funds comprised about 46 percent 
of the Social Security Administration's fiscal year 2002 administrative budget.  
The agency received another 16 percent from the Medicare Trust Funds, as well as 
37 percent from general revenues for administration of the Supplemental Security 
Income program. The SSA's total fiscal year 2002 administrative budget was $7.6 
billion.
    	Social Security's outlays and receipts were removed from the budget in 
three separate actions by Congress. However, the exemption from the discretionary 
caps was less clearly stated when the Budget Enforcement Act of 1990 was passed.  
Prior to discretionary caps, appropriations acts limited expenditures for 
administration through a "limitation on administrative expenses." When confusion 
arose over the intended treatment of administrative costs and the discretionary 
caps, both OMB and CBO eventually agreed that those costs would be subject to the 
discretionary caps, even though the program was an entitlement with its 
administration paid from Social Security tax receipts.
    	In both the President's budget and appropriations acts, the limitation on 
administrative expenses is used to prevent the Social Security Administration from 
an open ended administrative budget. In the Senior Citizens' Right to Work Act of 
1996, a separate exception to the discretionary caps was made through FY 2002 for 
CDR funding. Concerned that such reviews were lagging, Congress provided for 
additional spending for CDRs above a base amount that would not be constrained 
by discretionary caps.


HOUSE AND SENATE BUDGET PROCEDURES TO PROTECT SOCIAL 
SECURITY BALANCES

    	Under the budget rules that existed before 1991, Social Security was 
included in calculations of the budget deficit. This rule had the effect of 
potentially thwarting attempts to expand Social Security benefits or cut taxes 
if such attempts were not accompanied by measures to offset the cost or revenue 
loss. Floor objections could be raised against such actions if they violated the 
budget totals or allocations. If measures that raised benefits or cut taxes 
were enacted, other programs were potentially threatened with sequestration 
because the deficit would be made larger. The old process imposed the same 
fiscal discipline on Social Security as applied to other programs. Because 
Social Security is now exempt from the budget limits (except its administrative 
expenses), these fiscal constraints no longer apply. In their place are rules 
intended to make it difficult to bring up measures for a vote that would 
weaken the program's financial condition. These procedural rules are sometimes 
referred to as the Social Security "firewall" provisions.
    	In the House, a floor objection can be raised against a bill that 
proposes more than $250 million in Social Security spending increases or tax 
cuts over 5 years (counting the fiscal year it becomes effective and the 
following 4 years) unless the bill also contains offsetting changes to bring 
the net impact within the $250 million limit. Costs of prior legislation that 
fall within the 5-year period must be counted. An objection also can be raised 
against a measure that would increase long-range (75-year) average costs or 
reduce long-range revenues by at least 0.02 percent of taxable payroll.
    	In the Senate, budget resolutions must include separate amounts for 
Social Security income and outgo for the first year and 5-year period covered 
by the resolution (i.e., separate from the budget totals). These amounts cannot 
cause the balances of the Social Security Trust Funds to be lower than projected 
under current law. Measures that would do so are subject to an objection, 
which can be overridden only by a vote of three-fifths of the Senate. Once 
the resolution is enacted, subsequent measures that on balance would cause 
Social Security outlay increases or revenue reductions are also subject to 
objection, which again can be overridden only by a three-fifths vote.
    	The fiscal year 2000 budget cycle resulted in a new budget process, 
not formally written in the congressional or executive budget laws, but arising 
from the projections of budgetary surpluses at the time in both the OASDI 
off-budget account and the on-budget account. With both Congress and the 
President pledging not to spend any of the Social Security surplus by running 
an on-budget deficit, attempts were made to finance increased spending or tax 
reductions from the surplus in the on-budget or non Social Security surplus 
even if it resulted in spending over the discretionary caps or the PAY-GO 
rules. Commonly referred to as the Social Security lock box approach by 
legislators, it was designed to keep the Social Security surpluses from being
spent; surpluses were instead to be used to reduce the public debt until long 
term Social Security (and Medicare) reforms are enacted. In other words, the excess 
OASDI income was to no longer pay for other parts of government, but to be used 
to reduce the "publicly" held debt.  While this would have strengthened the 
government's fiscal position by lowering its indebtedness in advance of the baby 
boom retirement wave, it would have not, on its own, provided the money needed to 
pay the rapidly rising Social Security benefit outlays starting 2018 when the 
current level of Social Security tax receipts falls short of benefit costs.

LEGISLATIVE HISTORY

    	(For a description of legislative changes made in the 95th-102nd 
Congresses, refer to the 1996 Green Book; for changes in the 103rd Congress, see 
the 1998 Green Book.)

104th CONGRESS

Senior Citizens' Right To Work Act of 1996 (incorporated into Public Law 
104-121, the Contract With America Advancement Act of 1996):
	Authorizing additional CDR funds.--This legislation authorized additional 
administrative funding to enable the Social Security Administration to increase 
CDRs. Amounts spent for CDRs above the already assumed base funding levels are 
not subject to the discretionary spending caps through fiscal year 2002. SSA must 
report annually on CDR expenditures and savings to the Social Security, 
Supplemental Security Income, Medicaid and Medicare Programs.
    	Alleviating the Social Security earnings limit.--The act gradually raised 
the earnings limit for those between FRA and 70 to $30,000 by the year 2002, phased 
in over 7 years as follows:



Year                Prior Law         Law as altered by P.L. 101-121

1996                $11,520           $12,500 
1997                $11,880           $13,500 
1998                $12,240           $14,500 
1999                $12,720           $15,500 
2000                $13,200           $17,000 
2001                $13,800           $25,000 
2002                $14,400           $30,000 



    	Senior citizens between full retirement age (FRA) (age 65-67, depending on 
year of birth) and age 70 who earned over the given earnings limit would continue 
to lose $1 in benefits for every $3 earned over the new limit. After 2002, the 
annual exempt amounts were indexed to growth in average wages. The substantial 
gainful activity (SGA) amount applicable to individuals under FRA who are eligible 
for disability benefits on the basis of blindness was no longer linked to the 
earnings limit amount for those age FRA-69. As under prior law, this SGA amount 
continued to be wage-indexed in the future, and was projected to rise to $14,400 
by 2002.
    	Entitling of stepchildren to child's benefits based on actual dependency 
on stepparent support.--Benefits were made payable to a stepchild only if it is 
established that the stepchild is dependent on the stepparent for at least one-half 
of his financial support. In addition, benefits to the stepchild are to be 
terminated if the stepchild's natural parent and stepparent are divorced. The 
dependency requirement was made effective for stepchildren who become entitled or 
reentitled to benefits beginning in July 1996. In cases of a subsequent divorce, 
benefits to stepchildren will terminate 1 month after the divorce becomes final. 
Stepparents are required to notify SSA of the divorce. In addition, SSA is required 
to notify annually those potentially affected by this provision.
    	Removing drug addiction and alcoholism as disabling conditions.--An 
individual no longer is considered disabled for purposes of entitlement to cash 
Social Security and Supplemental Security Income disability benefits if drug 
addiction or alcoholism is the contributing factor material to her disability. 
Individuals with drug addiction or alcoholism who have another severe disabling 
condition (such as AIDS, cancer, cirrhosis) can qualify for benefits based on that 
disabling condition.
    	If a person qualifying for benefits based on another disability also is 
determined to be an alcoholic or drug addict incapable of managing his benefits, a 
representative payee will be appointed to receive and manage the individual's 
checks. Recipients who are unable to manage their own benefits as a result of 
alcoholism or drug addiction will be referred to the appropriate State agency for 
substance abuse treatment services. In each of fiscal years 1997 and 1998, $50 
million was authorized to fund additional drug (including alcohol) treatment 
programs and services. Individuals entitled to benefits before March 1996 remained 
eligible for benefits until January 1, 1997.
    	Studying efficacy of providing benefit and contribution Statements to 
recipients.--The Commissioner of Social Security was required to conduct a 2-year 
pilot study, beginning in 1996, of the efficacy of providing individual benefit and 
contribution information to recipients of Old-Age and Survivors Insurance (OASI) 
benefits.
    	Protecting the Social Security and Medicare Trust Funds.--This act codified 
Congress' understanding of present law that the Secretary of the Treasury and other 
Federal officials are not authorized to use Social Security and Medicare funds for 
debt management purposes. 
	Personal Responsibility and Work Opportunity Reconciliation Act of 1996 
Public Law 104-193):
    	This act prohibited payment of Social Security benefits to any noncitizen 
in the United States who is not lawfully present in the United States.  An 
exception was provided for any case in which nonpayment of a benefit would be 
contrary to a totalization agreement.  Section 233 of the Social Security Act 
prohibits totalization agreements from including provisions that are contrary 
to current Social Security law. Section 202(y) of the Social Security Act 
(added by P.L. 104-208-the "Illegal Immigration Reform and Immigrant Responsibility
Act of 1996") prohibits, without exception, payment of benefits to noncitizens in 
the United States if they have not been determined by the Attorney General to be 
lawfully present. Furthermore, it has been determined that none of the current 
totalization agreements include provisions that would require the payment of 
Social Security benefits to foreign nationals in the United States who are not 
lawfully present in the United States.  	Omnibus Consolidated Rescissions 
and Appropriations Act of 1996 (Public Law 104-134):
    	Providing for mandatory electronic funds transfers.--Federal payments, 
including Social Security and Supplemental Security Income benefits payable 
beginning after July 1996 to persons with bank accounts, must be paid by 
electronic funds transfer (EFT). All recurring Federal payments made after 
January 1, 1999 will be made by EFT, except that the Secretary of the Treasury 
may waive the requirement under certain circumstances.
    	Enhancing debt collection.--Provided SSA with permanent debt collection 
authorities, including administrative offset of other Federal benefit payments,
offset of Federal salaries, reporting of delinquent debt to credit bureaus, use 
of private collection agencies, and assessment of late charges.

105th CONGRESS

Revenue Reconciliation Act of 1997 (incorporated into Public Law 105-34):
    	Expanding SSA records for tax collection.--This provision provides that, 
for an application for a Social Security number (SSN) for a person under age 18, 
SSA must collect the SSNs of each parent, in addition to currently required 
evidence of age, identity, and citizenship, and share this information with the 
Internal Revenue Service for administration of tax benefits based on support or 
residency of a child. 
Excluding termination payments made to insurance salesmen.--Payments 
made to a self-employed insurance salesman after his agreement to work for the 
insurance company has terminated are excluded from Social Security coverage if: 
he performed no additional work for the company in that taxable year; he entered 
into a covenant not to compete with the company; and the amount of the payment 
was based entirely on the policies the salesman sold during the last year of the 
agreement which remain in force and not on his length of service or overall 
earnings from the company.

106th CONGRESS

Foster Care Independence Act of 1999 (Public Law 106-169):
    	Enforcing benefit restrictions for prisoners.--The Commissioner is required 
to share (on a reimbursable basis) information obtained under agreements with 
institutions reporting prisoners with other Federal or Federally assisted cash, 
food, or medical assistance programs to ensure that other Federal, State or local 
benefits do not inappropriately flow to prisoners.
    	Creating new administrative sanctions to deter abuse.--A new penalty is 
added to previous penalties for nonpayment of OASDI and SSI benefits for 
individuals found to have lied or misrepresented facts in applying for benefits. 
The penalty is a period of nonpayment of 6 months for the first violation, 
12 months for the second, and 24 months for the third such violation. A prior 
provision banning benefits for 10 years for individuals who misrepresent residence 
to claim benefits in two or more States is repealed.
    	Protecting Social Security funds.--Representative payees are made liable 
for an OASDI or SSI overpayment caused by a payment made to a beneficiary who has 
died. SSA must establish an overpayment control record under the representative 
payee's SSN. The legislation also bars from the OASDI and SSI programs 
representatives and health care providers found to have helped commit fraud; the 
bar from participation would last for 5 years, 10 years, and permanently for the 
first, second and third such finding, respectively.
    	Adding resources and legislative tools to combat fraud.--The Commissioner 
is required to consult with the Inspector General of SSA and the Attorney General 
regarding additional measures to combat fraud in Social Security's Disability 
programs, as well as methods for improving the processing of reported changes to 
beneficiaries' income. In addition, SSA must itemize funds needed to combat fraud 
in its annual budget. The legislation also provides for readier data exchanges 
with 
State and Federal agencies to ensure proper benefit payment.

Ticket to Work and Work Incentives Improvement Act of 1999 (Public Law 
106-170):
    	Creating new avenues to work and self-sufficiency.--Creates a new "Ticket
to Work" Program, to be implemented in all States within 4 years, under which the 
Social Security Administration would provide Social Security Disability Insurance 
(SSDI) and SSI disability beneficiaries with tickets they can use to purchase 
services to help them enter the work force. Services would be tailored to 
individual needs and choices, with providers paid for results when beneficiaries 
return to the work force or achieve certain milestones. To protect those who 
attempt to work but must return to benefits, certain rules are eased for 
requalifying for benefits for those in need due to failing health.
    	Expanding availability of health care services for the disabled.--For 
SSDI beneficiaries who go to work, the legislation extends Medicare coverage for 
an additional 4.5 year period beyond current law (for a total of 8.5 years). This 
provision also expands State options to provide Medicaid to workers with 
disabilities, provide grants to States to support workers with disabilities, 
create State demonstration programs to provide medical aid to workers with 
potentially severe disabilities, and hold down insurance costs for certain 
disabled workers.
    	Funding new studies and demonstration projects.--SSDI demonstration 
project authority is renewed for 5 years; SSA must conduct a project to study the 
incentives created by gradually reducing SSDI benefits $1 for every $2 in earnings 
over a set level. Several GAO and SSA reports are to be conducted on current work 
incentives for individuals with disabilities and on ways to improve such incentives. 
    	Ensuring changes are paid for.--The Ticket to Work law made a number of 
technical changes to Social Security to ensure that any new benefits are fully 
paid for, including: awarding certain prisons reporting inmate lists up to $400 per 
inmate found to be collecting Social Security benefits (preventing fraud and 
benefit overpayments); restricting Social Security benefits for certain sex 
offenders and prisoners jailed for under 1 year; allowing clergy members a 2 year 
"open season" to opt into Social Security; assessing a charge to cover administrative 
costs created by attorneys who have SSA process their fees; and clarifying rules 
related to the removal of drug addiction and alcoholism as disabling conditions 
under the SSDI and SSI Programs.  
Senior Citizens Freedom To Work Act (Public Law 106-182):
    	Eliminates the earnings limit as of the month the recipient attains the FRA, 
effective in 2000. In the year a recipient attains the FRA, the 1 for 3 reduction rate 
and the exempt amounts put in place by Public Law 104-121 will continue to apply.

                             107th CONGRESS

Department of Defense Appropriations Act for FY 2002 (Public Law 107-117):
    	Eliminates "deemed" extra wages credited to military service personnel 
beginning in calendar year 2002.

                            STATISTICAL TABLES

                     TAX RATES AND COVERED EARNINGS

TABLE 1-1 -- FICA AND SELF-EMPLOYMENT CONTRIBUTIONS 
ACT (SECA) TAX RATES AND MAXIMUM TAXABLE EARNINGS, 
SELECTED YEARS 1937-2004                                     




TABLE 1-2 -- OASDI AND HI TAX RATES FOR SELF-EMPLOYED 
INDIVIDUALS, 1980-2000 





TABLE 1-3 -- EARNINGS COVERED BY OASDI SYSTEM,  
SELECTED YEARS 1950-20021






TABLE 1-3 -- EARNINGS COVERED BY OASDI SYSTEM,  
SELECTED YEARS 1950-2002- continued




TABLE 1-4 -- FICA AND SECA TAX PAYMENTS FOR AVERAGE AND 
HIGH EARNERS, SELECTED YEARS 1950-2003






TABLE 1-5-AMOUNT OF COVERED WAGES NEEDED  
TO EARN ONE QUARTER OF COVERAGE,  
SELECTED CALENDAR YEARS 1978-2012










COVERED WORKERS

TABLE 1-6 -- ESTIMATED SOCIAL SECURITY COVERAGE, 2002 




TABLE 1-7 -- CIVILIAN WORKERS COVERED BY SOCIAL SECURITY 
SYSTEM, SELECTED YEARS 1939-2002  











TABLE 1-8 -- ESTIMATED SOCIAL SECURITY COVERAGE OF 
WORKERS WITH STATE AND LOCAL GOVERNMENT 
EMPLOYMENT, 20011                                  











TABLE 1-8 -- ESTIMATED SOCIAL SECURITY COVERAGE OF 
WORKERS WITH STATE AND LOCAL GOVERNMENT 
EMPLOYMENT, 2001- continued                               





TABLE 1-9 -- OASDI BENEFITS PAID, SELECTED YEARS 1940-2002      




BENEFIT AND RECIPIENT DATA

TABLE 1-10 -- OASDI BENEFICIARIES IN CURRENT PAYMENT 
STATUS AND NEW AWARDS, DECEMBER 2002  





TABLE 1-11 -- NUMBER OF PERSONS RECEIVING VARIOUS TYPES OF 
OASDI BENEFITS BY AGE, SEX, AND AVERAGE MONTHLY BENEFIT 
AMOUNTS, DECEMBER 2002









TABLE 1-12 -- PERCENTAGE OF PRIMARY INSURANCE AMOUNT 
(PIA) PAID FOR DEPENDENTS' AND SURVIVORS' BENEFITS










TABLE 1-13 -- NUMBER OF SOCIAL SECURITY RETIRED WORKER 
NEW BENEFIT AWARDS AND PERCENT RECEIVING REDUCED 
BENEFITS BECAUSE OF ENTITLEMENT BEFORE  FRA,  
SELECTED YEARS 1956-2002  







TABLE 1-14 -- PERCENTAGE OF WORKERS ELECTING SOCIAL 
SECURITY RETIREMENT BENEFITS AT VARIOUS AGES, 
SELECTED YEARS 1940-2002










TABLE 1-15 - EARNINGS HISTORIES FOR HYPOTHETICAL WORKERS 
AGE 62 IN 2003  









TABLE 1-16 - MONTHLY BENEFIT AMOUNTS CREDITED FOR 
SELECTED BENEFICIARY FAMILIES WITH FIRST ELIGIBILITY IN 
2003, FOR SELECTED WAGE LEVELS, DECEMBER 2003








TABLE 1-17 -- SOCIAL SECURITY REPLACEMENT RATES FOR 
HYPOTHETICAL WORKERS RETIRING AT FULL RETIREMENT 
AGE (FRA), SELECTED YEARS 1940-2080  











BENEFIT ADJUSTMENTS

TABLE 1-18 -- SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFIT INCREASES FROM THE 
BEGINNING OF THE PROGRAM THROUGH JANUARY 2004  










TABLE 1-19 -- COMPARISON OF AVERAGE WAGE INCREASES TO 
BENEFIT INCREASES AND CHANGES IN THE CPI, 1965-2002  









TABLE 1-20 -- INCREASES IN FULL RETIREMENT AGE  AND DELAYED RETIREMENT CREDITS WITH 
RESULTING BENEFIT, AS A PERCENT OF PRIMARY INSURANCE AMOUNT, PAYABLE AT  
SELECTED AGES, FOR PERSONS BORN IN 1924 OR LATER





TABLE 1-21 -- WINDFALL BENEFIT FORMULA FACTOR










EFFECT OF CURRENT EARNINGS AND TAXATION OF BENEFITS

TABLE 1-22 -- ANNUAL EARNINGS EXEMPT FROM THE 
EARNINGS LIMIT, SELECTED CALENDAR YEARS 1975-2012














TABLE 1-23 -- NUMBER OF RETIRED WORKERS WITH 
EARNINGS IN 20001










TABLE 1-24 -- MONTHLY SUBSTANTIAL GAINFUL ACTIVITY (SGA) 
AMOUNTS SINCE 1968









TABLE 1-25 -- EFFECT OF TAXING SOCIAL SECURITY BENFITS BY INCOME CLASS UNDER 2003 LAW  
(2000 POPULATION AND INCOMES)  







TABLE 1-26 -- TAXATION OF OLD-AGE, SURVIVORS, AND 
DISABILITY INSURANCE (OASDI) BENEFITS BY TRUST FUNDS 
CREDITED AND AS A PERCENTAGE OF TOTAL OASDI BENEFIT 
PAYMENTS, SELECTED FISCAL YEARS 1984-2008  









TABLE 1-27 -- WORKSHEET FOR DETERMINING THE TAXABLE 
PORTION OF SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS









TRUST FUND AND RELATED DATA

TABLE 1-28 -- ESTIMATED OPERATIONS OF THE COMBINED OASI 
AND DI TRUST FUNDS, IN CURRENT DOLLARS,  
SELECTED CALENDAR YEARS 2003-2040  









TABLE 1-29 -- ESTIMATED OPERATIONS OF THE COMBINED OASI 
AND DI TRUST FUNDS, IN CONSTANT 2003 DOLLARS,  
SELECTED CALENDAR YEARS 2003-2040  








TABLE 1-30 -- ESTIMATED TRUST FUND BALANCES AS A 
PERCENTAGE OF ANNUAL EXPENDITURES,  
SELECTED CALENDAR YEARS 2003-2040







TABLE 1-31 -- MAXIMUM TRUST FUND RATIOS AND YEAR OF 
EXHAUSTION FOR THE OASDI TRUST FUNDS UNDER 
ALTERNATIVE ASSUMPTIONS









TABLE 1-32 -- ESTIMATED INCOME RATES AND COST RATES, AS A PERCENTAGE OF TAXABLE 
PAYROLL, SELECTED CALENDAR YEARS 2003-2080







TABLE 1-33 -- ESTIMATED OASDI INCOME AND COST RATES AND 
ACTUARIAL BALANCES AS A PERCENTAGE OF TAXABLE 
PAYROLL OVER 25, 50, AND 75-YEAR PERIODS












TABLE 1-34 -- ESTIMATED COST OF OASDI AND HI PROGRAMS AS 
A PERCENT OF GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT (GDP),  
SELECTED CALENDAR YEARS 2003-80










TABLE 1-34 -- ESTIMATED COST OF OASDI AND HI PROGRAMS AS 
A PERCENT OF GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT (GDP),  
SELECTED YEARS 2003-2080- continued









TABLE 1-35 -- POPULATION, WORK FORCE, AND OASDI 
BENEFICIARY DATA AND DEPENDENCY RATIOS,  
SELECTED YEARS 1960-2040






TABLE 1-36 -- FERTILITY, DEATH RATE, AND PERIOD1 LIFE 
EXPECTANCY ASSUMPTIONS, SELECTED YEARS 1940-2080







TABLE 1-37 -- SELECTED ECONOMIC ASSUMPTIONS,  
SELECTED YEARS 1960-2080












TABLE  1-38 -- NET ADMINISTRATIVE EXPENSES AND 
ADMINISTRATIVE EXPENSES AS A PERCENTAGE OF BENEFIT 
PAYMENTS, FISCAL YEARS 1998-2002  










DISABILITY PROGRAM DATA

TABLE 1-39 -- NUMBER OF DISABILITY INSURANCE (DI) 
BENEFICIARIES, SELECTED YEARS 1960-2002







TABLE 1-40 -- PERCENT DISTRIBUTION BY AGE, SEX, AND EDUCATION OF TITLE II DISABLED 
WORKER BENEFICIARIES GRANTED BENEFITS IN SELECTED CALENDAR YEARS 1970-2002, 
COMPARED WITH ADULT U.S. POPULATION IN 2000







TABLE 1-41 -- PERCENT DISTRIBUTION BY DISABLING CONDITION OF TITLE II DISABLED 
WORKER BENEFICIARIES GRANTED BENEFITS IN SELECTED CALENDAR YEARS 1970-2002








TABLE 1-42 -- DISABLED WORKERS' APPLICATIONS, AWARDS, 
AWARDS AS A PERCENT OF APPLICATIONS,  
AND AWARDS PER 1,000 INSURED WORKERS,  
SELECTED CALENDAR YEARS 1965-2002                                                








TABLE 1-43 -- ADMINISTRATIVE LAW JUDGE DI DECISION 
RATES, INITIAL DENIALS AND TERMINATIONS,  
SELECTED FISCAL YEARS 1980-2002






TABLE 1-44 -- TITLE II CONTINUING DISABILITY REVIEW 
CESSATIONS AND CONTINUATIONS,  
SELECTED FISCAL YEARS 1977-2001









TABLE 1-45 -- DISABILITY CASES PENDING AND WAITING TIMES, 
FISCAL YEARS 1988-2002  









                                      APPENDIX
 RELATIONSHIP OF TAXES TO BENEFITS FOR SOCIAL SECURITY 
RETIREES--HOW LONG IT TAKES TO RECOVER THE VALUE OF 
TAXES PAID PLUS INTEREST

    	The issue of the relative value of Social Security benefits, compared to
the value of the payroll taxes paid to earn those benefits, is often brought up in 
discussions of the nature of the program. This comparison is complex and involves 
many judgments, and is not easily answered with general aggregate numbers. In 
addition to all the technical factors that must be addressed, the nature of the 
Social Security law complicates such computations. Not only do analysts disagree 
on the proper techniques to use in making calculations, there are often fundamental 
disagreements involving subjective factors: what work patterns to use; what part of 
the Social Security tax to count; whether to include the employer's share of the 
tax; and what rate of interest to use.
    	This analysis seeks to avoid judgmental conclusions by providing a range 
of illustrations that vary these subjective factors. It does not evaluate the 
"moneysworth" of Social Security (answering whether recipients get a good deal 
from their investment), nor does it provide an "actuarial analysis" of how whole 
age cohorts fare. Rather, it simply presents illustrations of the amount of time 
it takes, and is projected to take, to recover the value of taxes paid plus 
interest (Table 1-49). The illustrations represent a range of possible payback 
times, depending on variations in the assumptions used. In this way, no 
conclusions are made--but the illustrations allow readers to make their own 
judgments.
    Many things complicate any determination of the relationship of benefits 
of taxes for future retirees. For example, although Social Security tax rates 
and benefit formulas are set by law, they can be changed. Since Congress has 
modified taxes and benefits many times since the beginning of the program, it is 
clearly 
inconsistent with the program's history to calculate taxes and benefits into the 
future on the assumption that these key elements may not change.  Since the 
program's outgo is estimated to outstrip its tax revenue by 2018, and the trust 
fund balances are estimated to be exhausted 39 years from now, changes would 
become necessary at some point. These changes obviously would affect the 
relationship of taxes to benefits. However, the nature of future changes is 
unknown, whereas current law is a given. Therefore, in order to assess the 
relationship of future taxes and benefits, this analysis uses calculations that 
are useful in presenting possible outcomes of policies currently incorporated 
in the law.
    Calculations of the relationship of benefits to taxes for future retirees 
involve many key factors. The rate of Social Security taxation is set by law. 
The portion of the tax that provides cash benefits (Old-Age, Survivors, and 
Disability Insurance, or OASDI) to employees is 6.2 percent levied on both 
employees and employers. The old-age and survivors insurance portion of the 
tax from which retirement benefits are paid, is 5.3 percent, again, on both 
employees and employers. The tax rate applies to earnings up to a maximum amount. 
The "maximum taxable earnings" is $87,000 in 2003 but will rise in the future 
at the same rate as average wages in the economy. Therefore, the amount of Social 
Security taxes an employee will pay under current law is a direct function of her 
earnings. If one knows the amounts of an individual employee's earnings, and what 
the maximum taxable earnings are each year, the amount of tax paid is easily 
calculated.
    	Future initial benefit amounts are also in part a function of one's 
earnings. Benefits are computed at first eligibility (age 62 for retirement) by 
a method that indexes both earnings over the worker's career and the benefit 
formula to changes in average wages in the economy. After age 62, benefits rise 
in tandem with the cost of living. As these factors are unknown, future benefit 
amounts cannot be 
predicted with certainty.
    	Further complicating the issue is the nature of the program. As a "social 
insurance" program, Social Security has both social and insurance goals. The 
social-goal features provide a design that deliberately gives a better return on 
taxes to some workers than to others. For example, the basic formula for 
calculating Social Security benefits is tilted to replace a higher proportion of 
earnings for low-paid workers. Also, a complex array of dependents' benefits is 
available at no additional cost for workers with families.
    	As with insurance, the exact relationship of Social Security benefits 
received to total taxes paid cannot be predicted for each and every worker. 
Thus, workers who die before or shortly after retirement and leave no survivors 
may collect only a few dollars in benefits or perhaps none at all. Other workers 
may collect Social Security benefits for many years after retirement and receive 
benefits substantially greater than the value of their Social Security taxes. 
Workers who become disabled or die at an early age might have paid relatively 
little in Social Security taxes, but they or their families may receive benefits 
for many years, recovering the value of the worker's taxes many times.
    	There really is no "typical" Social Security beneficiary with a "typical" 
work history. An "average" benefit can be the result of many different work 
histories and thus be based on different amounts of taxes paid. For example, 
because the benefit formula does not require that all earnings be used in the 
benefit computation, workers with gaps in their earnings history may receive the 
same benefits as other workers, but pay less in total taxes.
    	Nevertheless, models can produce projections of future benefits, based on 
assumptions about wage and price growth, for workers with designated work 
histories and characteristics. This analysis makes such projections using several 
assumptions about illustrative workers. It assumes that each worker retires at 
age 65 in January of the designated year after having worked full time in 
employment covered by Social Security beginning at age 21. Similarly, all the 
illustrations reflect three lifetime earnings patterns--workers who always earned 
(1) the Federal minimum wage; (2) a wage equal to Social Security's "average 
wage series"; or (3) a wage equal to the maximum amount creditable under Social 
Security.
    	These work histories and characteristics are necessarily arbitrary. Many 
variations could be constructed that would alter the payback times. However, by 
comparing similar examples of workers in what may be considered illustrative 
situations one may make a number of observations without having to resolve all 
the judgmental questions concerning what constitutes a typical worker or having 
to provide a voluminous array of illustrations.
    	Calculations are based on the intermediate assumptions of the 2003 
Social Security Trustees' Report to forecast wage and price growth. Under these 
assumptions, wages grow for most of the projected period by 4.1 percent a year, 
prices by 3.0 percent.
    	Although using common assumptions and focusing on certain examples 
allows comparisons across generations, there are other factors that can be varied 
depending on one's view of the Social Security system. Among these is whether to 
count the employer's share of the payroll tax. Most economists agree that 
employees pay for the employer's share of the tax in the form of forgone wages or 
fringe benefits. However, some maintain that employers are actually paying for 
income maintenance protection that they would have to pay for anyway in one form 
or another in the absence of the Social Security Program, and that they absorb 
part of it and pass the rest along to the general public in the form of higher 
prices. This analysis does not attempt to resolve this debate, but rather presents 
examples using both assumptions.
    	Another variable subject to the reader's judgment is the proportion of 
the Social Security tax to apply to retirement benefits. The payroll tax consists 
of three elements--old-age and survivors insurance (OASI), disability insurance 
(DI), and hospital insurance (HI). Because the DI and HI Programs have earmarked 
taxes, their own trust funds, and designated tax rates specified in the law, they 
are clearly and easily excludable from computations of taxes that pay for 
retirement benefits. OASI taxes pay for survivor as well as retirement benefits, 
and it would be inconsistent to include taxes that pay for survivor benefits on 
the tax side, but not include the value of survivor benefits on the benefit side,
in computing payback times. However, there is no separate allocation of taxes in 
the law for survivor or old-age benefits. It is possible to derive hypothetical 
year-by-year tax allocations for old-age benefits by assuming that such taxes 
would be in the same proportion to OASI tax rates as old-age benefits are to 
OASI benefits for each year. The Social Security Administration's actuaries have 
year-by-year projections of these benefits and this analysis uses them to compute 
taxes attributable solely to old-age benefits. 
    	A problem with this approach is that the survivor portion of the tax 
cannot so easily be assigned to a benefit. While the DI and HI taxes protect 
against risks that really do not involve an element of choice--every worker could 
become too disabled to work or suffer illness in old age--there is an element of 
choice in whether a worker has dependents. Nevertheless, the worker still must pay 
the full OASI tax. An unmarried childless worker can maintain that it is inaccurate 
to say that only the old-age portion of the OASI tax should be used to compute the 
payback times of his retirement benefit when the worker is forced to pay a tax (the 
survivor portion of the OASI tax) for which he currently can derive no benefit. 
Also, it can be asserted that this approach understates the value of the 
accumulated taxes because it does not take account of the subsidy provided by 
workers who die before reaching retirement. However, such a subsidy is theoretical, 
whereas the illustrations refer to individuals who in fact have survived to 
retirement age and use the tax they actually would have paid. Because Social 
Security taxes are adjusted periodically to take account of current and projected 
program experience, it can reasonably be assumed that any subsidy effect is 
reflected in the rate of the OASI tax. Again, this analysis does not resolve the 
argument of whether to count the survivor portion of the OASI tax. It simply 
shows both ways of computing the relationship of benefits to taxes.
    	Of course, any calculation of such a relationship is heavily dependent 
on the interest rate assumptions used. The value of taxes over time is equivalent 
to their worth if invested. However, the amount of interest is not easily 
determinable. Were the value of taxes paid invested wisely its total real worth 
theoretically could be many times its nominal value. On the other hand, it is 
possible that the principal could be wiped out by poor investment choices. To 
obtain a middle ground, consisting of a reasonable and safe investment history,
one could assume that the value of taxes paid was always placed in U.S. Government
obligations. Excess Social Security taxes have always been invested in U.S. 
Government securities, so, to provide illustrations, we use the effective interest 
rates earned by the Social Security Trust Funds over the years and those projected 
for the future. Under the alternative II assumptions, average annual interest 
rates are projected ultimately to be 6.1 percent, a "real" interest rate of 3.0 
percent (i.e., 3.0 percent above inflation). The interest is assumed to be tax-free.
	 The cumulative value of taxes plus interest at the 3 different earnings 
levels for workers retiring in 2003 are shown in Tables 1-46, 1-47, and 1-48.

TABLE 1-46 -- SOCIAL SECURITY TAXES PAID BY A WAGE 
EARNER WHO HAS ALWAYS EARNED THE MINIMUM WAGE, 









TABLE 1-47 -- SOCIAL SECURITY TAXES PAID BY A WAGE EARNER 
WITH AVERAGE EARNINGS, 1959-20021





TABLE 1-48 -- SOCIAL SECURITY TAXES PAID BY A WAGE EARNER 
WITH MAXIMUM TAXABLE EARNINGS, 1959-2002







	Table 1-49 shows past and projected payback times for workers retiring in 
various years from 1940 to 2030. Benefits are for the worker alone. However, the 
value of the benefit could be higher if the worker had dependents who were eligible 
for benefits. For example, if these workers had spouses who also were the full 
retirement age (FRA) and were not entitled to a Social Security benefit on their own 
account, the value of the monthly benefit would increase by 50 percent. This would 
shorten the payback times considerably.
    While these illustrations do not address the "moneysworth" question, they do 
show the relationship of payback times of past, current, and future beneficiaries. 
It is apparent that past retirees quickly recovered the value of their taxes.  
Payback times have lengthened for workers retiring today, but they are still 
shorter than those projected for future retirees. This decline in value is 
ameliorated somewhat (especially for low-income workers) by the projection that 
future retirees are expected to live longer, and thus collect benefits longer. 
Table 1-50 shows the life expectancies for people turning age 65 in the 
illustrated years.
    	Defenders of Social Security tend to discount the phenomenon of 
lengthening payback times, arguing that the program serves social ends that 
transcend calculations of which individuals, or generations, obtain some sort of 
balance-sheet profit or loss. They point out that pay-as-you-go retirement systems 
such as Social Security by their nature often provide large returns on the 
contributions of the initial generations. In the early years of such programs, the 
ratio of workers to recipients is very high, allowing tax or contribution rates to 
be low. As the program matures, rates rise to reflect the increase in the number 
of beneficiaries. This feature is not unique to Social Security. Establishing 
benefit levels for early recipients in excess of what contributions would dictate 
also is found in private pension systems.
    	Furthermore, proponents of Social Security note that providing "adequate" 
benefits to initial Social Security recipients that were essentially "unearned" in 
relation to their contributions to the system was deliberate social policy. 
Providing a minimum level of protection to the first workers to participate in 
the system was considered more important, in a period of economic depression, 
than concerns about excessive rates of return on taxes paid. Besides, the social
benefits of giving a measure of economic independence for the elderly, and later 
for surviving spouses, and the disabled, are believed by many to be immense. Thus, 
some argue younger workers are in large part relieved from the financial burden 
of supporting their parents, and the elderly are afforded an opportunity to live 
independently and with dignity.
    	Critics of Social Security point to these social welfare features as a
basic flaw in the program. They argue that by combining the goals of social 
adequacy, which is welfare-related, with individual equity, which loosely ties 
benefits to taxes paid, the program has become a mishmash that accomplishes 
neither goal well and creates inequities. One inequity they cite is that future 
beneficiaries will receive retirement benefits inferior to those that the 
equivalence of their taxes could purchase in the private sector. They also say 
when interest is included, many workers (for example, those earning at least 
average wages; see Table 1-49) will not recoup what they and their employer
paid in taxes. Often buttressing these arguments are calculations that show 
what individuals could receive if their Social Security taxes were invested 
privately.
    	This latter argument is dependent on the interest rate assumed on 
private investment. Arriving at the "proper" interest rate is problematic. 
Those who project high investment returns often refer to the historical 
performance of the stock market, showing that a portfolio of broad-based 
stocks would have earned on average substantial rates of return over the years, 
and that this performance can be expected to recur in the future.
    	On the other hand, private investments have an element of risk that 
critics believe should be unacceptable in providing a national system of 
retirement income, and that if a safe-as-possible mix of investment vehicles 
were used instead, projected rates of return would be smaller. They also contend 
that recently real interest rates dropped dramatically and may not return to the 
high levels of the 1980s and 1990s. The key point for the reader is to be aware 
of the influence exerted by the projected rate of return in these sorts of 
calculations, and the large degree to which the argument about the value of 
Social Security hinges around it.

TABLE 1-49 -- NUMBER OF YEARS TO RECOVER TAXES PLUS 
INTEREST FOR VARIOUS WORKERS RETIRING AT AGE 65,1 
SELECTED YEARS 1940-2030








TABLE 1-50 -- LIFE EXPECTANCY AT AGE 65, SELECTED YEARS  
1940-2030







	REFERENCES

Advisory Council on Social Security. (1997, January). Report on the 1994-96 
Advisory Council on Social Security. Washington, DC: Author.
Ballantyne, H.C. (1984). Present policies and methods regarding the long-term 
adjustment of benefits. Social Security Bulletin, 47(10), 9-12.
Bipartisan Commission on Entitlement and Tax Reform. (1995, January). Final 
report to the President. Washington, DC: Author.
Board of Trustees, Federal Old-Age and Survivors Insurance and Disability 
Insurance Trust Funds. (2003, March 17). The 2003 annual report of the 
Board of Trustees of the Federal Old-Age and Survivors Insurance and 
Disability Insurance Trust Funds. Washington, DC: U.S. Government         
Printing Office.
Committee on Economic Security. (1935, January). Report of the Committee on 
Economic Security. Washington, DC: Author. (The report is available on 
the Social Security Administration's Website at: 
http://www.ssa.gov/history/reports/ces.html).
Kollmann, G. (2003). Social Security: The relationship of taxes and benefits for 
past, present, and future retirees (RL31034). Washington, DC: 
Congressional Research Service.
Social Security Administration. (2002). Annual Statistical Supplement to the 
Social Security Bulletin, 2002. Washington, DC.
  Although the FICA tax is shared between employers and employees, most economists 
agree that the total burden of the tax is borne by employees in the form of lower 
wages or fringe benefits.
  Elected office holders, political appointees, and judges are mandatorily covered 
by both OASDI and HI regardless of when their service began.
  Public Law 103-296 requires the Secretary of the Treasury to issue "physical 
documents" to the trust funds. Under prior practice, trust fund securities were 
recorded only electronically.
  The listing of impairments contains over 100 examples of medical conditions 
that are considered significant enough to prevent an individual from engaging in 
SGA. Each listing describes a degree of severity such that an individual who is not 
working, and has such an impairment, is considered unable to work by reason of the 
medical impairment. The listing describes specific medically acceptable clinical 
and laboratory findings and signs which establish the severity of the impairments. 
An impairment or combination of impairments is said to "equal the listings" if the 
medical findings for the impairment are at least equivalent in severity and duration 
to the findings of a listed impairment.
  Only one TWP is allowed in any one period of disability. By regulation, earnings 
of more than $580 a month in 2004 constitute "trial work."